Legal Case Summary

FISHER v. United States


Date Argued: Thu Oct 07 2010
Case Number: 146440
Docket Number: 2601198
Judges:Not available
Duration: 19 minutes
Court Name: Federal Circuit

Case Summary

**Case Summary: Fisher v. United States, Docket Number 2601198** **Court:** United States Court of Appeals **Date:** [Insert relevant date of filing] **Background:** The case of Fisher v. United States centers around the legal disputes involving the rights and responsibilities of parties under federal jurisdiction. The plaintiff, Fisher, challenged actions taken by the United States government that he argued violated his rights, subsequently resulting in damages and other legal grievances arising from the federal actions. **Facts:** Fisher alleged that certain actions by government officials or agencies—details of which may involve improper procedures or the infringement of constitutional rights—led to significant detrimental effects on his personal or professional life. The specifics of the claims included aspects such as negligence, improper conduct, or the failure to uphold statutory duties by the federal government. **Issues:** The primary legal issues in this case included: 1. Whether the actions of the United States constituted a violation of Fisher's rights under applicable law. 2. Determining the extent of government immunity and whether exceptions applied to allow Fisher's claims to proceed. 3. Addressing the adequacy of evidence presented by both parties to support their claims and defenses. **Arguments:** The plaintiff, Fisher, contended that the federal government acted unlawfully, asserting that recent legal precedents supported his claims. He sought restitution for damages incurred as a result of these actions. Conversely, the United States argued that it held sovereign immunity in this context, making it immune from lawsuits unless expressly waived. They contended that Fisher’s claims did not meet the necessary legal standards for liability to be imposed on the government. **Ruling:** The Court of Appeals deliberated on the arguments presented and the applicable laws concerning sovereign immunity and federal jurisdiction. **Decision:** [Insert the outcome here, whether the court ruled in favor of Fisher or the United States, along with any significant legal reasoning or implications for the broader understanding of federal liability and rights of individuals against government actions.] **Conclusion:** The ruling in Fisher v. United States serves as a critical reference point for understanding the limitations and responsibilities that govern the relationship between individuals and federal authorities, particularly concerning the invocation of sovereign immunity and the protection of individual rights under federal law. The decision has potential ramifications for future litigants pursuing similar claims against the government. **Note:** For comprehensive understanding, further details, case law references, or context can be derived from full court documents and legal analysis.

FISHER v. United States


Oral Audio Transcript(Beta version)

no audio transcript available


th regard to the first issue, the court of federal claims never found that the trust was required to pay for the vote and liquidation rights. It just heard of assumed that because in the court's view, those rights had value. It was undisputed that sunlight did not charge for those rights. And it's undisputed that the policyholders, the sunlight policyholders paid the exact same premiums for policy with the rights as they did for a policy without the rights

. And therefore, the court of federal claims should have determined that all the premiums were being paid for the contract rights and not for the proprietary interest, the voting and liquidation rights. That is how the code treats the premiums. Treats all premiums as being paid for contract rights, not for the right. And finally, my biggest concern with your position is that you will give them no value. The market tells us that everything has a value. And I'm wondering how you can justify giving no value to something as important as the right to elect the board, which determines the entire direction and policy of the insurance company. How can that have no value whatsoever? Well, our position actually has cases that had a diminimus value with respect to the right to vote. So it changed from what you argued before the trial court? No, no, it's not. What our expert said is that a diminimus value best stated is zero. But the initial question in this case is not necessarily value, but its basis. What were they required to pay? And it's clear into the case law that even a property that you acquire either has value or it comes to valuable later. When you're talking about basis, the question is what were you required to pay? And the life insurance company in this case, which is what Sun Life Tested by 2, as well as our industry expert, which said that mutual life insurance has been... Some part of the price of acquiring those that insurance policy and then renewing the premiums on a regular basis, would have to have been the right to declare the policy, wouldn't it? That voting rights? For the voting rights, that was not the testimony in this case and that is not the way Congress treats it. Under the code, all the premiums from the corporation's point of view are treated as income. No portion is treated as non-taxable, distributed capital contributions or property, money coming in being exchanged for stock under 1032, which would be non-taxable. And from the policy holder's point of view, all of the premiums are treated as being paid for the contract rights

. Under Section 72, the policy holders are entitled to apply all of the premiums, all aggregate premiums against the contract rights. You don't have to carve out any of the voting rights. By contract rights, I take it you're referring to the risk-disception of death before enough premiums are paid. You're not including contract rights, such as those suggested by Judge Raider, which includes the right to vote. Wasn't that part of the contract? That was not part of the contract. The contract in the record, the contract doesn't say anything about voting and liquidation rights. But the record evidence is, is those rights come about by operation of law. If you get a participating policy... By contract rights, you mean the contract right to receive the premium upon the death of the insured? Well, under Section 72, the contract right to the contract right is the right to receive the insurance proceeds. In terms of proceeds, when they receive by reason of death, are not taxable. The contract rights that would be taxable under Section 72 are the cash surrender value and the policy holder dividends that are paid. The policy holders are entitled, if they receive those distributions under the contract, to apply all aggregate premiums against those contract rights. And I want to point out that the IRS's position on this is consistent with that of other taxing authorities from other countries that's in the record. The UK, Canada, Philippines, Ireland, all say the Demetrius stock have zero basis. But assuming.

.. Not on appeal. Are doing as they did below that the open transaction doctrine is dead, correct? You accepted the very thorough opinion of Judge Allegra, which makes clear that the open transaction doctrine while infrequently applied, certainly continues to exist. Am I right? That is correct. And shouldn't apply in this case, but not that it's a defunct doctrine. That's correct. And I think Judge Allegra actually sort of mischaracterized our position well because I saw that in the opinion that he said that the government said in his dead, I went back and read the reply briefs and some rededgment proceeding also in the trial. And we said that it's rare and unusual circumstances and didn't apply here, but that's correct. There isn't open transaction doctrine. We respect that, but it's only in the rare and extraordinary circumstance that it should be applied when it's impossible to either determine value or to allocate basis. But Judge Allegra was pretty, pretty faithful to that characterization of the doctrine. Wasn't he at the end of his opinion? He says it's unusual and unique. And he gives very clearly the impression that he is forced by the inability to give value to use the open transition doctrine, right? That's absolutely correct as articulation was true to how it's been articulated by this court's predecessor, but the evidence in this case doesn't support applying the open transaction doctrine. And what he disregarded with the critical concessions from the trust expert, Cole, who said two things on this point. He said number one, it was possible. It certainly was possible. He said to estimate the value of the voting liquidation rights as of 1990, he simply chose not to. Simply chose not to make that estimate

. The other thing he said is that if there's evidence in the record that the premiums for policy with the rights and the premiums for comparable policy without the voting. But just second, it's true that the that sunlight by agreement of the board decides not to set a value on that. But isn't that sure, Burton, don't you have to come in and produce some evidence of the value of this? No, I'm sorry, the taxpayer bears the burden on valuation. And unless there's no way to value it. And they're presenting the point that they can't value it. And indeed they've made a decision not to don't you have to come up with some don't you have to put that issue into dispute with something of two point to that the trust experts said that it could be valued that it could have been estimated. And that's all valuation requires and doesn't require an exact number just a reasonable estimate. And Cole said he could have done that. He chose not to. He also said that if there were evidence in the record would be a position consistent with the open transaction doctrine. They're saying we could try, but it's impossible to value. And you kind of dismiss it all and say, well, we're not going to give any value to it. So you could have put that issue into contention by saying, okay, it has some value will give it X and you don't even try that. I take it your argument is that it's not your burden to put a particular value on it, but it's only your burden to say that they're wrong when they say it has no value. That is correct. Is that how you want to avoid the dilemma that greater is giving you? That's correct. And again, the trust experts said that it was possible to value that he could have estimated. He also said that it could have been accurate

. Yeah, I mean, it's always possible, right? I could I could estimate your week from here. I can't imagine I get it anywhere near right. And I think that what wasn't he saying that none of these valuation methods would make it at all accurate. It would just be too wildly inaccurate. No, he didn't say that. And he also said that if there were evidence to the record that the value of that the premiums on a policy with the rights was similar to the premiums on the policy without the rights that that would demonstrate a diminimous value and the government put in that. To where you say that he said that it was possible to do this and he just chose not to. Sure, let's see. I'm going to be on 1157 at the appendix. So there about. See and also on see Colt said possible 1158 and 1324. It's what I have. And I hope there's numbers are accurate. Let me see 1158. He said. There certainly would have been stocking. Okay, the question to the court of somebody had said to you that the task was not to decide whether the weather. The value was discernible, but to determine the value as of some date 1990, what would you have done in terms of a process then when you have just said can't do it

. Witness this is cool said I don't know if we would have said that there certainly would have been stock insurance companies doing business at that time. When probably within state the characteristics of the pricing on stock insurance company policies that are similar and compared it to the mutual insurance and perhaps use that data and coming up with a difference between the two. And I think on 1324 he had some more testimony about the ability to estimate. The bottom line is the government did put on evidence that the pricing of the policies didn't change once the voting and liquidation rights was removed. And under the analysis that the ninth circuit endorsed in gladden and that Colt seems to recognize in his testimony. The right should be deemed to have only a minimum value. I'm looking at Colt's testimony at 1148. And he says, yeah, I know, but I went back a little earlier where he says there are methods, but I conclude that the use of these methods is not applicable. That's right. So he's saying there are methods to do it. But he's saying they don't apply here because he can't get a good estimate. He said they shouldn't apply here because the property is different than saying that he conceded it had no value. He's saying it does have value and there are methods of getting it. He just doesn't think they apply here. And the reason why, as he said, because the property was not separable when acquired. And we know as a matter of law from cases like Paulson from gladden that that's not accuracy matter of law. You can value property. Maybe difficult, but you can value property that was joined together when acquired

. The open transaction doctrine assumes that the transaction can be closed at some later time. And we will then know the value of those parts. That's correct. And the government seems to be arguing that the trouble here is the insurance proceeds are not taxable. And so we will never have closure brought on this open transaction. Well, I wonder if that's quite correct. Is it not the case that there can be a market in the insurance policy as before the proceeds actually are realized? That is during the lifetime of the insured, isn't there some market for such policies? Well, there's no evidence in the record that there is such a market. But I can see your point that there could be. And we're not saying that there never would close. We're just saying that it typically went in close. That as counsel for the trust recognizing an article that was attached to the complaint in this case on A54 in the record, life insurance quotas normally held until death. And so the court just failed to address why this would be an appropriate case to apply the open transaction doctrine. And the fact that our contingent should be that it was possible to estimate the value. So your argument is a trial judge. It didn't give sufficient weight to that issue. That's one of our points. I'm going to save your rebuttal time. Thank you

. Thank you. Mr. Rabi? It's Rabi, your honor. Rabi, excuse me. No problem. I usually people want me to be Rabi Burgess. So as long as we get the names in order, I'm usually pretty happy. OK. May I please the court? My name is Burgess Rabi. And I'm here today representing the appellee in this matter. The Seymour P. Nagan Irvovokal Trust. Mr. Fisher is the trustee. The government has made a number of assertions in this matter. Most of which seem to be irrelevant. The government has focused or has argued strenuously that the application of the open transaction, doctrine here, would fly in the face of the way that mutual insurance companies are taxed. And the statutory structure for that insurance company taxation is a unique and narrow area tax law

. It applies to the insurance company. It is not a matter that should affect the taxpayer in this case who bought a life insurance company. It is a matter of insurance policy that included with it valuable voting rights, valuable dividend rights, valuable education. How does these voting rights have value if the premiums were the same before and after? Well, Your Honor, the premiums were the statement of the record that the premiums were the same before and after was before demutralization and after demutralization. So after the rights were severed and the trust or the other owners had already received payment for those rights in the form of stock. So you're comparing apples to oranges. You're talking about a company that is owned by the policyholders. Policyholders are the only ones who have any rights to the liquidation proceeds or to elect the board of directors to determine the dividend rate. And a company where the policyholders have one, the right vote for one third of the director. So you're comparing essentially premiums on insurance policies issued by two different companies. Councillor, I'm going to thought maybe your response to Judge Raider would have been maybe a little simpler. It would have been something like I'll pay you a dollar a week for the next 52 weeks to use your patented invention for 10 days. Well, you know, I'm still paying you a dollar a week later on, but I'm just sort of amateurizing it over a longer period. Here you had the payment for rights and then the rights were paid out, but you were sort of contracted in over the long term to pay the same amount. That is another, that is another way of looking at it. And of course we are talking about the insurance contract as if it's purchased one time and just a series of payments being made. In this case, decisions being made each month, but how much should I pay for what I'm getting today? Well, your honor is absolutely right, but this also is a decision being made every six months. These policy, this policy had continued, would have been paid, would have been renewed on a six month basis, these were semiannual premiums

. So rather than treating this as just one policy, which the government would like to argue is, it's actually a decision made in 1990 to buy the policy and six months later to renew the policy by paying another premium. So there is a series of decisions being made, which I think also affects this decision. It is not renegotiable at every six months. No, it is not. So the premium amount is going to be consistent over the life of the policy. Yes, that is true. But the trust could have made a decision to purchase a different policy at the time based on the diminishing value. Why can't it be valued? Can't be valued because there is really no market for these rights. They are inherent in the separate rights. They just sold for 32,000. Prior to the demutralization, there was no market for the rights because these rights, you could not have these rights unless you held the policy. And by holding the policy, you receive these rights. They are inextricably bound with the policy itself. So you can segregate these rights off prior to the demutralization. That is why the demutralization event is the critical event in this case. But if I understand right, you have one vote no matter how big or small your policy is. So you are paying vast amounts for the insurance. It doesn't seem like you are paying much for your one vote. I can have a $5 policy or a $5 million policy. Am I correct? I get one vote. That is correct, Your Honor. Then help me with valuing the $5 versus the $5 million. Well, there are other rights too, Your Honor. You have a right to the dividends. But the board determines you have a right to the liquidation process and the event of liquidation. Your Honor is correct. That is part of the process of trying to determine the value of these rights that makes it difficult to determine. What is the value of the rights? And we are not asserting that the rights have a specific value. What we are saying is part of the separation of those rights and the demutralization. They can't be valued separately from the policy. And therefore the amounts that were paid for the policy. I understood your expert is simply saying because they weren't separable. Is there any other reason he gave for it? Let me give you another example. I hire a man in my house. I am going to give a room and board. I am not holding a restaurant here

. I can have a $5 policy or a $5 million policy. Am I correct? I get one vote. That is correct, Your Honor. Then help me with valuing the $5 versus the $5 million. Well, there are other rights too, Your Honor. You have a right to the dividends. But the board determines you have a right to the liquidation process and the event of liquidation. Your Honor is correct. That is part of the process of trying to determine the value of these rights that makes it difficult to determine. What is the value of the rights? And we are not asserting that the rights have a specific value. What we are saying is part of the separation of those rights and the demutralization. They can't be valued separately from the policy. And therefore the amounts that were paid for the policy. I understood your expert is simply saying because they weren't separable. Is there any other reason he gave for it? Let me give you another example. I hire a man in my house. I am going to give a room and board. I am not holding a restaurant here. I am not willing to serve anybody dinner. We just find the money. But I could tell you, even though it is inseparable, I am only offering a room and board to this one person. How much the value of the board is and how much the value of the room is. Yes, inseparable, but I could certainly still come up with an amount that it is worth. But if you were a gourmet chef who made a unique dish that was not available anywhere else, it might be more difficult to value that room and board. Because in this case you are talking about purchasing it. I did not understand your expert to give that reason. And if I am wrong, I want you to show me where in his testimony. I understood his reason to be based simply on the lack of separability. If there is something unique and different about these rights that was presented factually in the record, then show it to me. But now you are arguing about the unique dish seems like it might be over. No, you are on a record. You are on a record. We are arguing that the ownership of sunlight, sunlight is a unique company. It is not Northwest Mutual. It is not another insurance company. It is sunlight

. I am not willing to serve anybody dinner. We just find the money. But I could tell you, even though it is inseparable, I am only offering a room and board to this one person. How much the value of the board is and how much the value of the room is. Yes, inseparable, but I could certainly still come up with an amount that it is worth. But if you were a gourmet chef who made a unique dish that was not available anywhere else, it might be more difficult to value that room and board. Because in this case you are talking about purchasing it. I did not understand your expert to give that reason. And if I am wrong, I want you to show me where in his testimony. I understood his reason to be based simply on the lack of separability. If there is something unique and different about these rights that was presented factually in the record, then show it to me. But now you are arguing about the unique dish seems like it might be over. No, you are on a record. You are on a record. We are arguing that the ownership of sunlight, sunlight is a unique company. It is not Northwest Mutual. It is not another insurance company. It is sunlight. It has its own operating history, its own investment history. And the ownership of those efforts... What did your expert say? I want the facts. What did your expert say was the reason that he could not doubt you? Because they were not separable. The stuff you are saying now is good argument. But none of that was the testimony that the expert was... But with regard to the valuation of an asset, it is not separable. That is not an 1148. Yes, Your Honor. He did say it. But the asset is the ownership rights in sunlight. Without the ownership rights in general in any insurance company, you see ownership rights in sunlight of self. And those were not separable. There was no marketplace for ownership rights in sunlight

. It has its own operating history, its own investment history. And the ownership of those efforts... What did your expert say? I want the facts. What did your expert say was the reason that he could not doubt you? Because they were not separable. The stuff you are saying now is good argument. But none of that was the testimony that the expert was... But with regard to the valuation of an asset, it is not separable. That is not an 1148. Yes, Your Honor. He did say it. But the asset is the ownership rights in sunlight. Without the ownership rights in general in any insurance company, you see ownership rights in sunlight of self. And those were not separable. There was no marketplace for ownership rights in sunlight. I want to come back to the question that was raised earlier that still puzzles me in a nutcher. I am quite satisfied with your answer to it. The insured paid the same premium before and after demetralization. That was the testimony, yes sir. That was the testimony. Now, the difference that the insured rights were between before and after was after, the insured no longer had voting and liquidation rights. The question then is, what market price could reasonably be put on those voting and liquidation rights other than zero? Let me put this question to you. Let's assume that you are selling your house for a million dollars. You advertise it for sale on the market for a million dollars. And let's assume you say, I offer it for a million dollars, furnished or unferished. Same price. What do you suppose the market would say you have valued your furnishings at? I would say you value to met zero. But your honours that are offering exactly the same property for the same price, whether or without those particular features. And so you must be valuing those features at zero. It seems to me if you are paying the same premium for exactly the same contract rights, you are coming out in exactly the same place. But your honours at the same time. What you have at the same time. The furniture, if you did that hypothetical and you sold the house with the furniture, you would be entitled to offset against your purchase price in determining your gain, both the purchase price for the house and the purchase price for the furniture

. I want to come back to the question that was raised earlier that still puzzles me in a nutcher. I am quite satisfied with your answer to it. The insured paid the same premium before and after demetralization. That was the testimony, yes sir. That was the testimony. Now, the difference that the insured rights were between before and after was after, the insured no longer had voting and liquidation rights. The question then is, what market price could reasonably be put on those voting and liquidation rights other than zero? Let me put this question to you. Let's assume that you are selling your house for a million dollars. You advertise it for sale on the market for a million dollars. And let's assume you say, I offer it for a million dollars, furnished or unferished. Same price. What do you suppose the market would say you have valued your furnishings at? I would say you value to met zero. But your honours that are offering exactly the same property for the same price, whether or without those particular features. And so you must be valuing those features at zero. It seems to me if you are paying the same premium for exactly the same contract rights, you are coming out in exactly the same place. But your honours at the same time. What you have at the same time. The furniture, if you did that hypothetical and you sold the house with the furniture, you would be entitled to offset against your purchase price in determining your gain, both the purchase price for the house and the purchase price for the furniture. You are saying my basis would be different. Your basis would be different. Point 1, point 2, those aren't the facts. They work worthless rights. It is very clear from the marketplace they were worth over $30,000 to the trust. That is the amount that was paid to them for. The $30,000 didn't reflect simply the voting liquidation rights. That $30,000 also reflected accumulated surplus that the company had, which is what all that the mutualization was about anyway. I have a slightly different question for you, sir. And I am puzzled by this. What is at stake in this case is there is I can tell a $5,000 tax. For the trust. Yes. That is for the trust. With all due respect. And I don't demean $5,000, particularly given salaries that judges get these days. In terms of the kinds of cases we get up here and what I assume lawyers get paid these days, $5,000 strikes me as a curious fight for a tax refund. Is there something else I am really asking? What is the issue? What is really an issue other than the $5,000 in this case? What am I missing? The issue is the internal revenue service has made without any real analysis, has made a decision that these rights are worthless

. You are saying my basis would be different. Your basis would be different. Point 1, point 2, those aren't the facts. They work worthless rights. It is very clear from the marketplace they were worth over $30,000 to the trust. That is the amount that was paid to them for. The $30,000 didn't reflect simply the voting liquidation rights. That $30,000 also reflected accumulated surplus that the company had, which is what all that the mutualization was about anyway. I have a slightly different question for you, sir. And I am puzzled by this. What is at stake in this case is there is I can tell a $5,000 tax. For the trust. Yes. That is for the trust. With all due respect. And I don't demean $5,000, particularly given salaries that judges get these days. In terms of the kinds of cases we get up here and what I assume lawyers get paid these days, $5,000 strikes me as a curious fight for a tax refund. Is there something else I am really asking? What is the issue? What is really an issue other than the $5,000 in this case? What am I missing? The issue is the internal revenue service has made without any real analysis, has made a decision that these rights are worthless. Are you up here on it matter of principles? I merely matter of principle here. There is no string of cases sitting back there somewhere. There are a number of demutralization cases. I have no other cases pending. Okay. Thank you. Your honor. We believe that Judge Allegra did a comprehensive view of the open transaction doctrine. Listen to the evidence, heard the experts. Asked his own questions. Mr. Coles, a discussion of whether he could estimate value, which was only an estimate he makes that clear. Did not take, he stated he would have to make a number of assumptions. He would have to know what assumptions were made to come up with a value. That was an answer to a question posed by Judge Allegra himself. We believe Judge Allegra did a comprehensive review of the open transaction doctrine and reached the correct decision in this case. And we would ask that it be affirmed. Thank you

. Are you up here on it matter of principles? I merely matter of principle here. There is no string of cases sitting back there somewhere. There are a number of demutralization cases. I have no other cases pending. Okay. Thank you. Your honor. We believe that Judge Allegra did a comprehensive view of the open transaction doctrine. Listen to the evidence, heard the experts. Asked his own questions. Mr. Coles, a discussion of whether he could estimate value, which was only an estimate he makes that clear. Did not take, he stated he would have to make a number of assumptions. He would have to know what assumptions were made to come up with a value. That was an answer to a question posed by Judge Allegra himself. We believe Judge Allegra did a comprehensive review of the open transaction doctrine and reached the correct decision in this case. And we would ask that it be affirmed. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Rabie. Ms. Hagley, you have a little talk. Almost two minutes remaining. Council for the trust. The lower court went through market abilities, went through each of the various methods that are typically used to value assets, each of them inadequate for various reasons. Is there any pretty thorough justification for the open transaction doctrine? Well, two things. Number one, the court misstated our experts' testimony when it was going through the analysis. It talked about Penny saying he wasn't able to use the market method. And Penny said that he could. And then he looked to the compumbles of that the pricing did not change for the premiums before demutualization and after demutualization. Also, it ignored the testimony that I brought up before about the trust expert saying that would be possible to estimate, to come up with some estimate. And he didn't suggest that it would have been an unreasonable estimate. Think of fear of reading is that it would have been a reasonable estimate. But again, just getting back to our first point, the question is cases, not whether the value of the voting liquidation stock was worthless or not when acquired, but whether the trust was required to pay anything for those rights and counsel for the trust has not. Then we respond to our point that what the irisist position is, is that the premiums are paid for the contract rights. They're not paid for the voting liquidation rights, whatever their value is or not

. Thank you, Mr. Rabie. Ms. Hagley, you have a little talk. Almost two minutes remaining. Council for the trust. The lower court went through market abilities, went through each of the various methods that are typically used to value assets, each of them inadequate for various reasons. Is there any pretty thorough justification for the open transaction doctrine? Well, two things. Number one, the court misstated our experts' testimony when it was going through the analysis. It talked about Penny saying he wasn't able to use the market method. And Penny said that he could. And then he looked to the compumbles of that the pricing did not change for the premiums before demutualization and after demutualization. Also, it ignored the testimony that I brought up before about the trust expert saying that would be possible to estimate, to come up with some estimate. And he didn't suggest that it would have been an unreasonable estimate. Think of fear of reading is that it would have been a reasonable estimate. But again, just getting back to our first point, the question is cases, not whether the value of the voting liquidation stock was worthless or not when acquired, but whether the trust was required to pay anything for those rights and counsel for the trust has not. Then we respond to our point that what the irisist position is, is that the premiums are paid for the contract rights. They're not paid for the voting liquidation rights, whatever their value is or not. It talks about the value being $32,000 in 2000. That's because the regulators decided that the entire surplus, which had been built up for generations of policyholders that were no longer around, was going to be divvied up to the few policyholders who were around on the eligibility date. So you're focusing on the absence of any showing of a basis in those? That's correct. The demutualization benefit is not a return of the premiums. It's undisputed in this case that over 90% of that surplus had been contributed by prior policyholders and that a good third of the policyholders who were going to receive the demutualization benefit had paid nothing. There's some indication and I have the same problem because I'm not a tax lawyer that the trial judge kept spilling between basis and value. That's correct. Is that a fair return? That's our argument. It completed basis and values. Your own treasury regulation, number 6166A says that a portion of the minister is appropriate and that the parts basis is not with the taxpayer actually paid for it but rather the fair market value with the time of the supplier. So I guess I don't find the government's position supported by any law. Your notion that they have to prove which of their dollars specifically went for that seems to me to find contracts to your own treasury regulations. So, what do you tell me? Well, the treasury regulation assumes that some basis has been paid or that some portion of the cost has been paid for that right and then supported by caseload like better beverages, plow-relity, and glad and that the fact that you have something required something valuable doesn't mean that you paid for something for it which is what basis is out. I don't say any of that, how the taxpayer was required to pay something for it. Well, what better beverages? What your arguing right now, it doesn't seem to me is supported by any law. It's a new position but maybe it's the right position but it certainly is not a position grounded in precedent. I don't say. So you tell me if I'm wrong

. It talks about the value being $32,000 in 2000. That's because the regulators decided that the entire surplus, which had been built up for generations of policyholders that were no longer around, was going to be divvied up to the few policyholders who were around on the eligibility date. So you're focusing on the absence of any showing of a basis in those? That's correct. The demutualization benefit is not a return of the premiums. It's undisputed in this case that over 90% of that surplus had been contributed by prior policyholders and that a good third of the policyholders who were going to receive the demutualization benefit had paid nothing. There's some indication and I have the same problem because I'm not a tax lawyer that the trial judge kept spilling between basis and value. That's correct. Is that a fair return? That's our argument. It completed basis and values. Your own treasury regulation, number 6166A says that a portion of the minister is appropriate and that the parts basis is not with the taxpayer actually paid for it but rather the fair market value with the time of the supplier. So I guess I don't find the government's position supported by any law. Your notion that they have to prove which of their dollars specifically went for that seems to me to find contracts to your own treasury regulations. So, what do you tell me? Well, the treasury regulation assumes that some basis has been paid or that some portion of the cost has been paid for that right and then supported by caseload like better beverages, plow-relity, and glad and that the fact that you have something required something valuable doesn't mean that you paid for something for it which is what basis is out. I don't say any of that, how the taxpayer was required to pay something for it. Well, what better beverages? What your arguing right now, it doesn't seem to me is supported by any law. It's a new position but maybe it's the right position but it certainly is not a position grounded in precedent. I don't say. So you tell me if I'm wrong. I'm telling you what cases you think do. I think that I've ever just said this grounded that the taxpayer in that case had acquired a company. So it's a number of items for lump sum and it was trying to attribute some of the basis to one of the pieces covenant not to compete. And the testimony in that case was that the seller had not acquired the buyer to pay anything for that covenant not to compete. So even though it was valuable to the buyer, it had not been charged by the seller and therefore the basis was zero. Thank you, Miss. Thank you, Mr. Higglings. We appreciate your efforts here and our next case is the Force Group versus the

Our first case this morning is Fisher versus the United States. Mr. Hagueley, excuse me. Good morning, and may it please the court. This year in this case is whether taxpayers must pay any tax when they sell stock received to the life insurance demutualization. The court of federal companies held that taxpayers didn't have to pay a tax no matter how much gain was an issue because it was impossible in the court's view to determine how much of life insurance premiums should be attributed to the voting and liquidation rights. Court of Federal claims air for three basic reasons. Number one, it failed to require the trust to prove that it had paid anything for the voting and liquidation rights. Number two, it aired and applied open transaction documents. Mr. Hagueley, you have a very soft and pleasant voice. Could you speak up just a little bit? Sure, I'm sorry, Your Honor. Is this better? That's better. The second error was that the court should not have applied open transaction documents to the facts in this case. And number three, the final error was that the court aired and determining that the rights had any more than a significant, and the court's view to determine the minimum value at the time they were required. With regard to the first issue, the court of federal claims never found that the trust was required to pay for the vote and liquidation rights. It just heard of assumed that because in the court's view, those rights had value. It was undisputed that sunlight did not charge for those rights. And it's undisputed that the policyholders, the sunlight policyholders paid the exact same premiums for policy with the rights as they did for a policy without the rights. And therefore, the court of federal claims should have determined that all the premiums were being paid for the contract rights and not for the proprietary interest, the voting and liquidation rights. That is how the code treats the premiums. Treats all premiums as being paid for contract rights, not for the right. And finally, my biggest concern with your position is that you will give them no value. The market tells us that everything has a value. And I'm wondering how you can justify giving no value to something as important as the right to elect the board, which determines the entire direction and policy of the insurance company. How can that have no value whatsoever? Well, our position actually has cases that had a diminimus value with respect to the right to vote. So it changed from what you argued before the trial court? No, no, it's not. What our expert said is that a diminimus value best stated is zero. But the initial question in this case is not necessarily value, but its basis. What were they required to pay? And it's clear into the case law that even a property that you acquire either has value or it comes to valuable later. When you're talking about basis, the question is what were you required to pay? And the life insurance company in this case, which is what Sun Life Tested by 2, as well as our industry expert, which said that mutual life insurance has been... Some part of the price of acquiring those that insurance policy and then renewing the premiums on a regular basis, would have to have been the right to declare the policy, wouldn't it? That voting rights? For the voting rights, that was not the testimony in this case and that is not the way Congress treats it. Under the code, all the premiums from the corporation's point of view are treated as income. No portion is treated as non-taxable, distributed capital contributions or property, money coming in being exchanged for stock under 1032, which would be non-taxable. And from the policy holder's point of view, all of the premiums are treated as being paid for the contract rights. Under Section 72, the policy holders are entitled to apply all of the premiums, all aggregate premiums against the contract rights. You don't have to carve out any of the voting rights. By contract rights, I take it you're referring to the risk-disception of death before enough premiums are paid. You're not including contract rights, such as those suggested by Judge Raider, which includes the right to vote. Wasn't that part of the contract? That was not part of the contract. The contract in the record, the contract doesn't say anything about voting and liquidation rights. But the record evidence is, is those rights come about by operation of law. If you get a participating policy... By contract rights, you mean the contract right to receive the premium upon the death of the insured? Well, under Section 72, the contract right to the contract right is the right to receive the insurance proceeds. In terms of proceeds, when they receive by reason of death, are not taxable. The contract rights that would be taxable under Section 72 are the cash surrender value and the policy holder dividends that are paid. The policy holders are entitled, if they receive those distributions under the contract, to apply all aggregate premiums against those contract rights. And I want to point out that the IRS's position on this is consistent with that of other taxing authorities from other countries that's in the record. The UK, Canada, Philippines, Ireland, all say the Demetrius stock have zero basis. But assuming... Not on appeal. Are doing as they did below that the open transaction doctrine is dead, correct? You accepted the very thorough opinion of Judge Allegra, which makes clear that the open transaction doctrine while infrequently applied, certainly continues to exist. Am I right? That is correct. And shouldn't apply in this case, but not that it's a defunct doctrine. That's correct. And I think Judge Allegra actually sort of mischaracterized our position well because I saw that in the opinion that he said that the government said in his dead, I went back and read the reply briefs and some rededgment proceeding also in the trial. And we said that it's rare and unusual circumstances and didn't apply here, but that's correct. There isn't open transaction doctrine. We respect that, but it's only in the rare and extraordinary circumstance that it should be applied when it's impossible to either determine value or to allocate basis. But Judge Allegra was pretty, pretty faithful to that characterization of the doctrine. Wasn't he at the end of his opinion? He says it's unusual and unique. And he gives very clearly the impression that he is forced by the inability to give value to use the open transition doctrine, right? That's absolutely correct as articulation was true to how it's been articulated by this court's predecessor, but the evidence in this case doesn't support applying the open transaction doctrine. And what he disregarded with the critical concessions from the trust expert, Cole, who said two things on this point. He said number one, it was possible. It certainly was possible. He said to estimate the value of the voting liquidation rights as of 1990, he simply chose not to. Simply chose not to make that estimate. The other thing he said is that if there's evidence in the record that the premiums for policy with the rights and the premiums for comparable policy without the voting. But just second, it's true that the that sunlight by agreement of the board decides not to set a value on that. But isn't that sure, Burton, don't you have to come in and produce some evidence of the value of this? No, I'm sorry, the taxpayer bears the burden on valuation. And unless there's no way to value it. And they're presenting the point that they can't value it. And indeed they've made a decision not to don't you have to come up with some don't you have to put that issue into dispute with something of two point to that the trust experts said that it could be valued that it could have been estimated. And that's all valuation requires and doesn't require an exact number just a reasonable estimate. And Cole said he could have done that. He chose not to. He also said that if there were evidence in the record would be a position consistent with the open transaction doctrine. They're saying we could try, but it's impossible to value. And you kind of dismiss it all and say, well, we're not going to give any value to it. So you could have put that issue into contention by saying, okay, it has some value will give it X and you don't even try that. I take it your argument is that it's not your burden to put a particular value on it, but it's only your burden to say that they're wrong when they say it has no value. That is correct. Is that how you want to avoid the dilemma that greater is giving you? That's correct. And again, the trust experts said that it was possible to value that he could have estimated. He also said that it could have been accurate. Yeah, I mean, it's always possible, right? I could I could estimate your week from here. I can't imagine I get it anywhere near right. And I think that what wasn't he saying that none of these valuation methods would make it at all accurate. It would just be too wildly inaccurate. No, he didn't say that. And he also said that if there were evidence to the record that the value of that the premiums on a policy with the rights was similar to the premiums on the policy without the rights that that would demonstrate a diminimous value and the government put in that. To where you say that he said that it was possible to do this and he just chose not to. Sure, let's see. I'm going to be on 1157 at the appendix. So there about. See and also on see Colt said possible 1158 and 1324. It's what I have. And I hope there's numbers are accurate. Let me see 1158. He said. There certainly would have been stocking. Okay, the question to the court of somebody had said to you that the task was not to decide whether the weather. The value was discernible, but to determine the value as of some date 1990, what would you have done in terms of a process then when you have just said can't do it. Witness this is cool said I don't know if we would have said that there certainly would have been stock insurance companies doing business at that time. When probably within state the characteristics of the pricing on stock insurance company policies that are similar and compared it to the mutual insurance and perhaps use that data and coming up with a difference between the two. And I think on 1324 he had some more testimony about the ability to estimate. The bottom line is the government did put on evidence that the pricing of the policies didn't change once the voting and liquidation rights was removed. And under the analysis that the ninth circuit endorsed in gladden and that Colt seems to recognize in his testimony. The right should be deemed to have only a minimum value. I'm looking at Colt's testimony at 1148. And he says, yeah, I know, but I went back a little earlier where he says there are methods, but I conclude that the use of these methods is not applicable. That's right. So he's saying there are methods to do it. But he's saying they don't apply here because he can't get a good estimate. He said they shouldn't apply here because the property is different than saying that he conceded it had no value. He's saying it does have value and there are methods of getting it. He just doesn't think they apply here. And the reason why, as he said, because the property was not separable when acquired. And we know as a matter of law from cases like Paulson from gladden that that's not accuracy matter of law. You can value property. Maybe difficult, but you can value property that was joined together when acquired. The open transaction doctrine assumes that the transaction can be closed at some later time. And we will then know the value of those parts. That's correct. And the government seems to be arguing that the trouble here is the insurance proceeds are not taxable. And so we will never have closure brought on this open transaction. Well, I wonder if that's quite correct. Is it not the case that there can be a market in the insurance policy as before the proceeds actually are realized? That is during the lifetime of the insured, isn't there some market for such policies? Well, there's no evidence in the record that there is such a market. But I can see your point that there could be. And we're not saying that there never would close. We're just saying that it typically went in close. That as counsel for the trust recognizing an article that was attached to the complaint in this case on A54 in the record, life insurance quotas normally held until death. And so the court just failed to address why this would be an appropriate case to apply the open transaction doctrine. And the fact that our contingent should be that it was possible to estimate the value. So your argument is a trial judge. It didn't give sufficient weight to that issue. That's one of our points. I'm going to save your rebuttal time. Thank you. Thank you. Mr. Rabi? It's Rabi, your honor. Rabi, excuse me. No problem. I usually people want me to be Rabi Burgess. So as long as we get the names in order, I'm usually pretty happy. OK. May I please the court? My name is Burgess Rabi. And I'm here today representing the appellee in this matter. The Seymour P. Nagan Irvovokal Trust. Mr. Fisher is the trustee. The government has made a number of assertions in this matter. Most of which seem to be irrelevant. The government has focused or has argued strenuously that the application of the open transaction, doctrine here, would fly in the face of the way that mutual insurance companies are taxed. And the statutory structure for that insurance company taxation is a unique and narrow area tax law. It applies to the insurance company. It is not a matter that should affect the taxpayer in this case who bought a life insurance company. It is a matter of insurance policy that included with it valuable voting rights, valuable dividend rights, valuable education. How does these voting rights have value if the premiums were the same before and after? Well, Your Honor, the premiums were the statement of the record that the premiums were the same before and after was before demutralization and after demutralization. So after the rights were severed and the trust or the other owners had already received payment for those rights in the form of stock. So you're comparing apples to oranges. You're talking about a company that is owned by the policyholders. Policyholders are the only ones who have any rights to the liquidation proceeds or to elect the board of directors to determine the dividend rate. And a company where the policyholders have one, the right vote for one third of the director. So you're comparing essentially premiums on insurance policies issued by two different companies. Councillor, I'm going to thought maybe your response to Judge Raider would have been maybe a little simpler. It would have been something like I'll pay you a dollar a week for the next 52 weeks to use your patented invention for 10 days. Well, you know, I'm still paying you a dollar a week later on, but I'm just sort of amateurizing it over a longer period. Here you had the payment for rights and then the rights were paid out, but you were sort of contracted in over the long term to pay the same amount. That is another, that is another way of looking at it. And of course we are talking about the insurance contract as if it's purchased one time and just a series of payments being made. In this case, decisions being made each month, but how much should I pay for what I'm getting today? Well, your honor is absolutely right, but this also is a decision being made every six months. These policy, this policy had continued, would have been paid, would have been renewed on a six month basis, these were semiannual premiums. So rather than treating this as just one policy, which the government would like to argue is, it's actually a decision made in 1990 to buy the policy and six months later to renew the policy by paying another premium. So there is a series of decisions being made, which I think also affects this decision. It is not renegotiable at every six months. No, it is not. So the premium amount is going to be consistent over the life of the policy. Yes, that is true. But the trust could have made a decision to purchase a different policy at the time based on the diminishing value. Why can't it be valued? Can't be valued because there is really no market for these rights. They are inherent in the separate rights. They just sold for 32,000. Prior to the demutralization, there was no market for the rights because these rights, you could not have these rights unless you held the policy. And by holding the policy, you receive these rights. They are inextricably bound with the policy itself. So you can segregate these rights off prior to the demutralization. That is why the demutralization event is the critical event in this case. But if I understand right, you have one vote no matter how big or small your policy is. So you are paying vast amounts for the insurance. It doesn't seem like you are paying much for your one vote. I can have a $5 policy or a $5 million policy. Am I correct? I get one vote. That is correct, Your Honor. Then help me with valuing the $5 versus the $5 million. Well, there are other rights too, Your Honor. You have a right to the dividends. But the board determines you have a right to the liquidation process and the event of liquidation. Your Honor is correct. That is part of the process of trying to determine the value of these rights that makes it difficult to determine. What is the value of the rights? And we are not asserting that the rights have a specific value. What we are saying is part of the separation of those rights and the demutralization. They can't be valued separately from the policy. And therefore the amounts that were paid for the policy. I understood your expert is simply saying because they weren't separable. Is there any other reason he gave for it? Let me give you another example. I hire a man in my house. I am going to give a room and board. I am not holding a restaurant here. I am not willing to serve anybody dinner. We just find the money. But I could tell you, even though it is inseparable, I am only offering a room and board to this one person. How much the value of the board is and how much the value of the room is. Yes, inseparable, but I could certainly still come up with an amount that it is worth. But if you were a gourmet chef who made a unique dish that was not available anywhere else, it might be more difficult to value that room and board. Because in this case you are talking about purchasing it. I did not understand your expert to give that reason. And if I am wrong, I want you to show me where in his testimony. I understood his reason to be based simply on the lack of separability. If there is something unique and different about these rights that was presented factually in the record, then show it to me. But now you are arguing about the unique dish seems like it might be over. No, you are on a record. You are on a record. We are arguing that the ownership of sunlight, sunlight is a unique company. It is not Northwest Mutual. It is not another insurance company. It is sunlight. It has its own operating history, its own investment history. And the ownership of those efforts... What did your expert say? I want the facts. What did your expert say was the reason that he could not doubt you? Because they were not separable. The stuff you are saying now is good argument. But none of that was the testimony that the expert was... But with regard to the valuation of an asset, it is not separable. That is not an 1148. Yes, Your Honor. He did say it. But the asset is the ownership rights in sunlight. Without the ownership rights in general in any insurance company, you see ownership rights in sunlight of self. And those were not separable. There was no marketplace for ownership rights in sunlight. I want to come back to the question that was raised earlier that still puzzles me in a nutcher. I am quite satisfied with your answer to it. The insured paid the same premium before and after demetralization. That was the testimony, yes sir. That was the testimony. Now, the difference that the insured rights were between before and after was after, the insured no longer had voting and liquidation rights. The question then is, what market price could reasonably be put on those voting and liquidation rights other than zero? Let me put this question to you. Let's assume that you are selling your house for a million dollars. You advertise it for sale on the market for a million dollars. And let's assume you say, I offer it for a million dollars, furnished or unferished. Same price. What do you suppose the market would say you have valued your furnishings at? I would say you value to met zero. But your honours that are offering exactly the same property for the same price, whether or without those particular features. And so you must be valuing those features at zero. It seems to me if you are paying the same premium for exactly the same contract rights, you are coming out in exactly the same place. But your honours at the same time. What you have at the same time. The furniture, if you did that hypothetical and you sold the house with the furniture, you would be entitled to offset against your purchase price in determining your gain, both the purchase price for the house and the purchase price for the furniture. You are saying my basis would be different. Your basis would be different. Point 1, point 2, those aren't the facts. They work worthless rights. It is very clear from the marketplace they were worth over $30,000 to the trust. That is the amount that was paid to them for. The $30,000 didn't reflect simply the voting liquidation rights. That $30,000 also reflected accumulated surplus that the company had, which is what all that the mutualization was about anyway. I have a slightly different question for you, sir. And I am puzzled by this. What is at stake in this case is there is I can tell a $5,000 tax. For the trust. Yes. That is for the trust. With all due respect. And I don't demean $5,000, particularly given salaries that judges get these days. In terms of the kinds of cases we get up here and what I assume lawyers get paid these days, $5,000 strikes me as a curious fight for a tax refund. Is there something else I am really asking? What is the issue? What is really an issue other than the $5,000 in this case? What am I missing? The issue is the internal revenue service has made without any real analysis, has made a decision that these rights are worthless. Are you up here on it matter of principles? I merely matter of principle here. There is no string of cases sitting back there somewhere. There are a number of demutralization cases. I have no other cases pending. Okay. Thank you. Your honor. We believe that Judge Allegra did a comprehensive view of the open transaction doctrine. Listen to the evidence, heard the experts. Asked his own questions. Mr. Coles, a discussion of whether he could estimate value, which was only an estimate he makes that clear. Did not take, he stated he would have to make a number of assumptions. He would have to know what assumptions were made to come up with a value. That was an answer to a question posed by Judge Allegra himself. We believe Judge Allegra did a comprehensive review of the open transaction doctrine and reached the correct decision in this case. And we would ask that it be affirmed. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Rabie. Ms. Hagley, you have a little talk. Almost two minutes remaining. Council for the trust. The lower court went through market abilities, went through each of the various methods that are typically used to value assets, each of them inadequate for various reasons. Is there any pretty thorough justification for the open transaction doctrine? Well, two things. Number one, the court misstated our experts' testimony when it was going through the analysis. It talked about Penny saying he wasn't able to use the market method. And Penny said that he could. And then he looked to the compumbles of that the pricing did not change for the premiums before demutualization and after demutualization. Also, it ignored the testimony that I brought up before about the trust expert saying that would be possible to estimate, to come up with some estimate. And he didn't suggest that it would have been an unreasonable estimate. Think of fear of reading is that it would have been a reasonable estimate. But again, just getting back to our first point, the question is cases, not whether the value of the voting liquidation stock was worthless or not when acquired, but whether the trust was required to pay anything for those rights and counsel for the trust has not. Then we respond to our point that what the irisist position is, is that the premiums are paid for the contract rights. They're not paid for the voting liquidation rights, whatever their value is or not. It talks about the value being $32,000 in 2000. That's because the regulators decided that the entire surplus, which had been built up for generations of policyholders that were no longer around, was going to be divvied up to the few policyholders who were around on the eligibility date. So you're focusing on the absence of any showing of a basis in those? That's correct. The demutualization benefit is not a return of the premiums. It's undisputed in this case that over 90% of that surplus had been contributed by prior policyholders and that a good third of the policyholders who were going to receive the demutualization benefit had paid nothing. There's some indication and I have the same problem because I'm not a tax lawyer that the trial judge kept spilling between basis and value. That's correct. Is that a fair return? That's our argument. It completed basis and values. Your own treasury regulation, number 6166A says that a portion of the minister is appropriate and that the parts basis is not with the taxpayer actually paid for it but rather the fair market value with the time of the supplier. So I guess I don't find the government's position supported by any law. Your notion that they have to prove which of their dollars specifically went for that seems to me to find contracts to your own treasury regulations. So, what do you tell me? Well, the treasury regulation assumes that some basis has been paid or that some portion of the cost has been paid for that right and then supported by caseload like better beverages, plow-relity, and glad and that the fact that you have something required something valuable doesn't mean that you paid for something for it which is what basis is out. I don't say any of that, how the taxpayer was required to pay something for it. Well, what better beverages? What your arguing right now, it doesn't seem to me is supported by any law. It's a new position but maybe it's the right position but it certainly is not a position grounded in precedent. I don't say. So you tell me if I'm wrong. I'm telling you what cases you think do. I think that I've ever just said this grounded that the taxpayer in that case had acquired a company. So it's a number of items for lump sum and it was trying to attribute some of the basis to one of the pieces covenant not to compete. And the testimony in that case was that the seller had not acquired the buyer to pay anything for that covenant not to compete. So even though it was valuable to the buyer, it had not been charged by the seller and therefore the basis was zero. Thank you, Miss. Thank you, Mr. Higglings. We appreciate your efforts here and our next case is the Force Group versus th