Legal Case Summary

Horne v. Department of Agriculture


Date Argued: Wed Mar 20 2013
Case Number: 12123
Docket Number: 581732
Judges:Not available
Duration: 52 minutes
Court Name: Supreme Court

Case Summary

**Case Summary: Horne v. Department of Agriculture, Docket Number 581732** **Court:** United States Supreme Court **Decided:** June 22, 2015 **Citation:** Horne v. Department of Agriculture, 135 S. Ct. 2419 (2015) **Facts:** The case revolves around the Horne family's involvement in raisin farming in California. The Horne family, led by Marvin Horne, operated a raisin business and was subject to the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937. This federal law allowed for the establishment of marketing orders that aimed to stabilize raisin prices by controlling supply. Under these regulations, raisin producers were required to set aside a certain percentage of their crop for the government without compensation, essentially acting as a form of price control for the broader market. Marvin Horne and his family contested the government’s requirement that they surrender a certain percentage of their raisins to the Department of Agriculture without payment. They claimed this seizure of their property constituted a violation of the Fifth Amendment, which prohibits the taking of private property for public use without just compensation. **Issue:** The primary legal question was whether the government's seizure of raisins constituted a "taking" under the Fifth Amendment, thus requiring just compensation. **Holding:** The Supreme Court ruled in favor of the Horne family, determining that the government's requirement to surrender a portion of their raisins was indeed a form of taking under the Fifth Amendment. The Court emphasized that the government's action must be scrutinized under the Takings Clause, and that the Horne family was entitled to just compensation for the raisins seized. **Reasoning:** The Supreme Court noted that the requirement to turn over a portion of their crop for government use without compensation was a direct violation of property rights. The Court distinguished between regulations that serve an economic purpose and outright seizures of property. The Horne family’s raisins were considered personal property, and the Court underscored the protection of private property within the Constitution. The government could not take private property without offering compensation, regardless of the rationale behind the seizure. **Impact:** This ruling reaffirmed property rights under the Fifth Amendment, highlighting the necessity of compensation for the government when it expropriates private property. It set an important precedent in agricultural law and indicated a more protective stance toward private property against administrative actions. The decision reinforced the notion that even regulatory actions that are economically motivated cannot unjustly deprive individuals of their property rights. **Conclusion:** The decision in Horne v. Department of Agriculture underscored the balance between government regulatory powers and individual property rights, asserting that any government taking of private property must be accompanied by just compensation to comply with constitutional protections.

Horne v. Department of Agriculture


Oral Audio Transcript(Beta version)

We will hear argument first this morning in case 12-123 Horn versus Department of Agriculture. Mr. McHull? Mr. Chief Justice and may it please the Court. There is a surprising number of difficult merits questions lurking in this case, mostly involving whether there was a taking and if so, how it should be conceptualized and valued. Could I just stop you on a factual matter because it has confused me. As I look at the captions of the cases, there appear to be two different partnerships. One partnership known as Raisin doing businesses, Raisin Valley Farms, has Mr. Horn and his wife as the partners. Larson Valley, the producer, not the producer, the handler, has four other, the horns plus two other people. So, who owns the raisins? Isn't that the first partnership of the husband and wife and isn't the handler a second partnership that does the business of handling? The other two partners in Larson were Laura Horn's parents now deceased. But the estates have been substituted. That's right. So, isn't it two legal entities, one who owns and one who handles? One partnership produces one partnership handles? The Department of Agriculture did not distinguish among them. Well, I don't care if they did or they didn't. I mean, we should know. Are they two separate legal entities? One, two, three. They are separate legal entities all effectively controlled by the same family. Well, that's, you know, in the cap, you get some limited liability by creating separate entities. So, the creature who owns is one partnership and the entity that produces, that handles is a second one. I assume this is one of those difficult merits questions you are alluding to. It doesn't go to whether there's jurisdiction, but to whether the claim of a taking can be asserted by the partnership in question. Isn't it? That's right, Justice. I don't see how it goes to jurisdiction, which is the only question before. Well, it does in my mind because what is the claim assuming that the producer owns the producer entity owns the raisins? What exactly is being taken from the handlers? Is it the percentage, it can't be the raisins because they don't own them? Well, Justice Sotomayor, I'm delighted to preview our argument on the merit on that. What is it being taken from the handler entity? The order in this case was issued against the horns in their capacity as a handler only. So, the entire fine I was paid by them, none of the fine is attributable to anyone in their capacity as a producer. All right. So, go back. What is the, what was taken from them? You're saying it's just the fine? The fine is it taking? Or what was the interest that their claiming was taken by the government? They didn't own the raisins

. So, they get paid a fee for handling. So, this is our position, Justice Sotomayor. I think we have to look at what is it that the Department of Agriculture attempted to take? So, in the demand letter from the Department of Agriculture addressed to the horns, they ask the horns to deliver California raisins or the dollar equivalent. So, that's the fact upon which all of this case is built. Now, what is the legal significance of that? California raisins or the dollar equivalent? It is our legal position, or it will be our legal position on the merits, that when the government seeks a specific physical property, a Reese, or its monetary equivalent, that that is a taking of the Reese itself. And there's support for that and the precedent from this Court. The closest case is village of Norwood versus Baker. In this case, the city condemned a strip of land for the purpose of building a road. They tried to get out of paying any compensation by claiming that the abutting landowner would gain value. That was rejected. They were assessed a $2,000 compensation for the taking. And then the city turned around and issued a special assessment against the land owner for precisely that $2,000. The landowner came back up to this Court and this Court held that it was a taking, a taking of the land in a subsequent case just a couple of years later, the Court described this as a, quote, actual confiscation of private property to public use. But you begin by saying that these are merits defenses, but you wanted to focus first on the jurisdictional question this before us. That's right. I hope it helps to inform the jurisdictional question. But the jurisdictional question is this. The Ninth Circuit held that my clients could not even raise their takings claim on the merits until they had first gone to the Court of Clams. I think there are three things wrong with that. That might be true. And my right in thinking that there is no dispute on that point that they taking claim could have been asserted by the horns as producers in the Court of Federal Clams. I think that the government no longer disputes, although you should ask them to be clear. I think that they no longer dispute that this is not a jurisdictional point, even though they prevailed after the petition for rehearing was filed in the Court of Appeals on the Federal Law. The jurisdictional or not, as a practical matter, produces who are not subject to fine as handlers, but the producers of the raisins whose raisins are being segregated. Could they go to the Court of Federal Clams and say my raisins have been taken? The whether the claim is being brought in the capacity of producer or handler, I think is not relevant to one of our arguments and it is relevant to the other argument. But I just want to give a straight answer to that question. You are representing producers, and they just produce. No, no, no. We are representing people who are both producers and not members

. Hypothetically. Hypothetically. Is the Court of Federal claims the proper form for a producer? It depends upon whether the taking has been from them or not. In the ordinary case, the ordinary relationship between a producer and a handler, the producer is not paid for the reserve raisins, and therefore any payment that would come and any lawsuit on behalf of those raisins would go to the producer, and that would go, I think, to the Court of Clams. In this case, though, the business models quite different from that, and the producers in this case were paid everything. They received full, valid market value for their raisins. The only people who are outing money in this case are the horns in their capacity as handler. So that is why they are the only people in the field. The problem is that they were entitled to that money, meaning they had to pay it over to the producer. The producer was going to pay them a handling fee, but that money didn't belong to them, it belonged to the producers who supplied them with the raisins and expected payment for them. I'm not sure. If they were sold in the ordinary court. I'm not sure which money you were, if they have not asserted any claim on any money, the producers have been completely paid off. It is the handlers who have been held responsible, and the reason they were held responsible was the following logic. And you see this on page 78 of the Judicial Office's opinion. They were held responsible because in their processing capacity, when they were doing the stemming, the seeding, the fumigating, the packing, that this was regarded by the Department of Agriculture as possession, physical possession of the raisins, and acquisition of the raisins, even though they never had title to the raisins. It's the Department of Agriculture that has attached to them a possessory interest in the raisins, and then assess them the full monetary equivalent of those raisins, full market value, $484,000 for the market value because it's under this very unusual regulatory scheme, the government regards them as having possessed the raisins, even though that is not. Kagan, I'm sorry. Could I along the lines of what Justice Ginsburg was saying? Suppose that the horns had given over all the raisins, right? But that they thought that this was improper, that this marketing order was a violation of the takings clause, could they have gone to the court of claims via the Tucker Act and said, we want our money back? They gave over the raisins the question, they say, where entitled to compensation? Could they have gone through the court of claims? If they had not been paid for the raisins, they had taken raisins to a handler, received no money for them, I think that they could go to the court. In other words, the horns did what the marketing orders suggested they should do. They gave over the raisins, but they said, this is just improper. You're saying they could go to the court of claims? Okay. So if that's the case, I guess then the question is, why didn't they have to go that route? They didn't go that route, and the question, I think, is what are the consequences of that? Right. Because what they knew was that they were not going to be compensated for the raisins, and therefore they came up with a plan, a business plan, that they believed made eliminated any handler and made it unnecessary for any of the independent producers on whose behalf they're operating to turn over raisins to the government. The plan was ultimately rejected, and we haven't brought a cert petition on it, but the plan actually complies with the language of the regulation because they believe that in their capacity as handler, as processor, that they never required the raisins. Acquisition is the key term for becoming a handler under the rule, and they believe that since they were simply providing a service for $12 a ton, to their neighbors, that they never acquired the raisins, they never possessed the raisins. Some of the raisins were their own. One had to come out of the raisins where they were owned. At least as to that, that wouldn't be true, right? That's correct

. I think that's correct. To get you back to the jurisdiction point, let's just assume a hypothetical case where regulated entity has to pay an exact which it deems to be a penalty, and let's assume it can go to the court of claims, but it doesn't. It waits until the penalties assess, and then when the penalties assess, it says this is a take. Is that the case that you want to discuss with us today? That's right. When the underlying order would be a taking, and they have been assessed money because they comply with the taking, we believe they can challenge that as a taking, and both under the AMAA procedures in which are exclusive, I think that they have to go through the through the Department of Agriculture and the to the District Court, but I also think under the principles of the announced by this Court and the Appthel decision that they are entitled to a remedy in the District Court. Kagan asked, Mr. McDonnell, would you explain if there were just handlers who weren't producing any raisins, if there were just handlers, do they have a claim and where? And if there were just producers, I take it from the question I asked, and the question just as Kagan asked, that if there were just producers, the raisins got set aside, they were paid for only the ones that went to market. They could go to the Court of Plains. But now they're just handlers, as this entity is for most of the raisins that are involved some 80 percent, right? It's only about 20 percent as they were owned. So could this work for someone who was just a handler, doesn't produce any raisins? So if they are just a handler, as the Department of Agriculture treated them, as far as the Department of Agriculture is concerned, they are only a handler, that they were required to raise their exhaust their claims before the Department of Agriculture and then challenge the order in the District Court. Kagan, but I'm trying to understand, is this scheme, apparently it wasn't enough just to be a handler or just to be a producer? The claim that you're making turns on the coincidence of being both a producer and a handler. I don't think that that's so. I think that the horns ought to prevail on either, in either of their concerns. So any handler, any handler could be making the same claim? Any handler who has a business model that is similar to this, but most handlers. What's the business model that's similar to this? So some most handlers, if they're in compliance with the order, they take all the raisins from the producers, they only pay for the free pool raisins, they don't pay for the reserve raisins, and they never have any interest in the reserve raisins. And in this case, the horns did not operate that way. The producers receive full value for all of their raisins, so the producers are not in the case. They have no standing, they have no pocketbook injury. The entire pocketbook injury in this case is borne by the horns in their capacity as a handler. I'm sorry. In the normal's model, the handlers buy or buy the free raisins and then pay the producers as that would be. And so that's the difference in this model. They don't take title to the raisins is what you're saying. Exactly. And the horns believed that this would mean that they were not handlers. And that was, and they were found to be handlers in. What is the value in permitting a party who doesn't own property, to raise a taking claim on behalf of other people, meaning doesn't the system have an interest in ensuring that people comply with their legal obligations? And to the extent that you choose to violate the law, the way they have here, that the fine is punitive and not compensatory, meaning you don't own the raisins, but you were obligated to put raisins aside for someone else, you were their agent, and you failed to meet a government obligation that was independently on you. So I go back to my question, what was the taking since you didn't own the raisins, the taking is the fine is what you want to take. The taking is what the government demanded, which is either give me your house or give me your money, give me your raisins or give us the property equivalent

. They're not your raisins. By the time this order was enforced, the raisins were gone, and so is a practical matter, only one of those two alternatives was what. And to the rest of the Schindsberg's question, that you said the producers could go to the Court of Federal claims to contest the taking of the producers could go to contest the taking of raisins. If they had not been paid for the raisins, if they had not been paid for it, but are you, does that mean you do not think that the AMAA withdraws Tucker-Act jurisdiction? It withdraws Tucker-Act jurisdiction only for handlers. So if we're telling the pure producers, pure producers do not go to the, don't have to go through the AMAA process. Why, why does it withdraw for the one and not the other? These New Deal era programs, Justice Scalia, or somewhat, the, the, I mean the policy reason, what in the law lead you to that conclusion? Well, this is straightforwardly set forth in the, in the, in sections 14A and 15A of the AMAA. I don't think that's in dispute. So only producers are, are regulated by this program. Only producers have a right to go through their remedies in the Department of Agriculture. Only producers have to do that. It's, it's, it's, it's completely, it's, I'm sorry, I'm sorry, excuse me. Each of those was hand, please substitute the word handler for each of those. It's only the handlers that are regulated under this, under this program. So, and, and, and my clients were treated as handlers. They believe that they were not, but it is the Department of Agriculture that has attached this, this status to them. And it's, it's, I think quite a catch 22 for the government to come along and say, although we are finding you $700,000 in your capacity as a handler, you're not a handler for purposes of challenge. I might, I might, I might, I might get to what you're arguing about. And I might be off base by now. I feel like handlers, purchaser is raisins. I, like an old habit in the Stella, I just want to see that I'm, that I'm right. Tell me, just say you're wrong and I don't go into it further wrong. But the, the, there are some people they've been, they are either, they have some raisins, all right. And, and these particular people whom the, the department has said, have acquired the raisins. They said they acquired the raisins. And so they're, they're with some raisins. And then the government says, do this thing with your raisins. And they don't want to do it. So they don't. So they don't do it, even though the law says do it

. And then they say the law is unconstitutional. And moreover, you find us. Huge amount of money. And we don't want to pay it. It's the law is unconstitutional. And we consider that money that we paid, call it a fine, call it what you want. But we consider we shouldn't have paid it. And now we want it back and we want compensation. And we think it's a taking. And where do we go? Can't we make that argument in the Ninth Circuit? It's something like that. And that will be our own most exact, all right. But not quite. X. With, with one detailed difference. Yes. That this is the proceeding here that decides whether they have to pay. They have not yet paid the fine. Okay. So we shouldn't have to pay because this is all unconstitutional. And now what you argue. So they're raising a defense. It isn't that they are, it isn't that they're getting, I got it. And then the Ninth Circuit says go to the Court of Claims. And you say no, we don't have to go to the Court of Claims. But that detail actually is quite important because remember you can't even go to the Court of Claims unless you are seeking damages for an actual violation that has already taken place. We could not go to the Court, the warrants could not go to the Court of Claims right now. What the government says is that they should pay the $700,000 fine first and then go to the Court of Claims to get it back. And that is exactly what this Court said in AppFell is a, quote, pointless set of activities that Congress could not possibly have contemplated. I think that's true, Mr

. McConnell, is part of the fine, the part of the fine fools under AppFell, but not the other part. As to the compensation part, it seems to me you have a pretty decent AppFell argument. But as to the penalty part, I don't really understand how the AppFell argument would go. It seems to me that as to the penalty part, the key thing is that if they had handed over the raisins, they could have gone to the Court of Claims and had the compensation done there. And the fact that the government is penalizing them for not complying with the marketing order, it's not full within the rationale of AppFell. Well, the most pertinent case for that part of the fine, for the penalty part is Missouri Pacific Railroad versus Nebraska. So this is a case where the railroad was told by the State to do some, some expensive work. Railroad says no, that would be a taking if we were required to do that. There is no compensation available. And so they don't do it. They're fine $500. That gets up to this Court, and an opinion by Mr. Justice Holmes. The Court holds that that is a taking, and that the railroad is entitled to challenge the taking in the form of the fine. So for the penalty portion, the punishment portion of the fine, Missouri Pacific Railroad is actually the more pertinent decision. Which comes back, I don't think I fully answered all the variants of Justice Sotomayor to do is to get you on the basic argument which you started with, which is why is there, why was the Ninth Circuit wrong when they said they had no jurisdiction to hear this that rather they had to go, you had to go to the, is it? I mean, I took off the three reasons. One is it has nothing to do with jurisdiction. Second, the Tucker Act does not apply to cases where there is a defense being lodged to a monetary exaction. That's app fell as supplemented by Missouri Pacific Railroad. And third, even if that were not so, the AMAA displaces the Tucker Act, and they were required to exhaust their remedies before the Department of Agriculture and take their case to the district court in which they are resolved. First, I forgot the first already. What was the first? The first is that it isn't jurisdictional. And therefore, it's not in case it's jurisdictional. What is jurisdictional? The requirement to go to the court of claims when you need to is not jurisdictional that that's a matter of remedy. That is, it's the equitable principle that you may not pursue your case for an injunctive relief when there's an adequate and a remedy at all. Mr. McConnell, if the producers had decided to challenge this as a Tucker Act violation, they would have had to hand over the raisins, or could they have just held on to the raisins and said, I'm not handing it over until I get just compensation. So had they held on to their own raisins and sold them, I assume, you don't not just let them rot, if they had sold them, then the Department of Agriculture would have called them a handler because anyone who sells raisins is called a handler. And then they would be fined in their capacity as a handler, and it would be a somewhat similar case to this one

. All right. Maybe an easier one than that. Well, the point is that under a normal takings claim, you have to hand over your property. You have lost the value, and you want the government to pay it back to you, correct? Not necessarily correct. There are a whole string of cases in which property owners raise takings as a defense, rather than turning over the property, Kaiser Ratna is perhaps the most best known recent case, but out of an administrative context, there's the Florida power and light case. Pencentral was like this, Loretto versus Teleprompter is like this. There's a whole string of cases. The government themselves cite six such cases, most of them fairly old, for this proposition. So there's nothing unusual about bringing a defensive takings claim. Mr. Kahn, I don't want to encroach on your rebuttal time, but what one mysterious thing, the first time around, the Ninth Circuit decided this case on the merits. So if you're right, I take it. We remand, and then they adjudicate the merits of the takings claim, but they already did that. Yes, Justice Ginsburg. And they did that on a ground that we think is manifestly inconsistent with this Court's precedence. We were prepared to, we were trying to get an unbunk review, and we're prepared to come to this Court from the merits determination. We were blocked from that because the government after the petition for rehearing was filed came up with calling this a jurisdictional argument, raised a subjection for the first time, and the Ninth Circuit panel accepted their view, issued a new opinion stripping out the entire merits and substituting this jurisdictional holding that is producing so much enjoyment for us this morning. May I reserve the remaining time? Thank you. Thank you, Mr. McConnell. Mr. Palmore. Thank you, Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the Court. I'd like to start where Justice Sotomayor started with Petitioner's Council, because any takings analysis needs to begin with a careful identification of what property was allegedly taken. Petitioners in this case have actually advanced two different theories about what property of theirs was taken, what taking is that issue here, raisins and money. We think both takings claims fail for threshold reasons, but they're different threshold reasons that call for different analysis. Mr. Palmore, before you do that, then have you conceded the point that this is not jurisdictional? We agree that the failure to go to the Court of Claims is not properly viewed as a jurisdictional defect

. We did invoke Ninth Circuit precedent below stating that it was jurisdictional, and some of this case's, this Court's case is put it in rightness terms, which is an Article III concept. So there have been a few. When did you first raise the argument that it was jurisdictional in our opposition to the rehearing petition? And now you're changing back again and saying it's not. There was Ninth Circuit precedent holding that it was jurisdictional, and we relied on that, and there's certainly language from it. You relied on that when you got to rehearing. You didn't rely on that before you went before the Ninth Circuit, right? That's correct. We think this is properly viewed as a substantive defect in the claim. So in a sense, the Ninth Circuit and its initial panel decision ruled for the government on kind of substantive defect one, there's no taking. And what it did on rehearing in our view, although it attached the wrong label to it, it substantively was correct in concluding that there was substantive defect in the claim. But Mr. Palmore, if you're conceding now that this is not jurisdictional, it seems to me that your Tucker Act argument as a substantive argument, I mean, has been waived. You didn't raise that argument until the rehearing petition. That would certainly be something that the Ninth Circuit could consider in the event that were a remand here, but the Ninth Circuit did decide it. The substance of its bottom line conclusion was correct, and all of its analysis was correct. It simply used the wrong word, so we think it is here. And what? Well, I'm really confused. You're saying there ought to be a remand here, because the question is not jurisdiction, which is just what your friend says, right? Well, the Ninth Circuit did. But still if you're in agreement, it ought to go back to the Ninth Circuit, they should do it on the merits, and if that's wrong, we can review that. Look, if that happens, of course, as Justice Ginsburg pointed out, the consequence for us is they reinstate the prior panel opinion. Well, that may well be. Also, I'm not going to resist too strenuously that kind of remand, but they did decide it, and moreover, they decided something separate, which is at J.A.305, they said something different, which is the kind of threshold defect in the taking claim turning on raisins, which is there's a capacity problem. So there are two problems with a raisin claim, a capacity problem and a just compensation problem. The capacity problem is this. In 2002, after having been strictly raisin producers since 1969, entering into a market where there was a reserve requirement from the beginning, they knew what they were getting into, they decided to adopt a new business model, as Petitioner's Council says, but as was found below, they adopted a business model that was an intentional, willful attempt to evade regulatory requirements in order to secure an unfair competitive advantage. But what they did was they took on the obligations of a handler. They became raisin handlers in 2002, and what came with that status were a series of regulatory obligations that apply only to handlers and under the AMAA can apply only to handlers. The requirement to have raisins inspected the requirement to file truthful reports, the requirement to make records available, and the requirement to separate out raisins into what's called free tonnage and reserve tonnage

. Any raisins processed doesn't matter who owns them. Those are handler specific regulatory obligations that were imposed upon them, and they violated every single one of them, willfully and intentionally in order to secure an unfair competitive advantage. And what the USDA did was impose penalties on them for the violation of law that attached to them only as raisin handlers, and then they have invoked the judicial review proceedings in Section 14 that provides a judicial review mechanism only for handlers. But part of that penalty was, you know, your raisins or your life, right? I mean, it was, you don't have to pay the penalty if you give us the raisins. That's not correct, Justice Scalia. They have to give the raisins. Mr. McConnell referred to demand- I mean, they are under a regulatory obligation to provide the raisins. If they violate that regulatory obligation, they are subject to sanctions. One component that amounts to the same thing, your raisins or the penalty? No, but it's not a choice, and I think that's very important to point out. There were actually two different demand letters. Mr. McConnell referred to a demand letter saying, your raisins or your money. There was an initial demand letter saying, you are a handler, you have to comply. We're going to come get the raisins. The second demand letter said, we showed up, literally, it says, we showed up with our truck. You didn't provide the raisins. So now you've got to provide the cash equivalent, and there were also going to be, as there were, separate regulatory proceedings brought against them for violating those obligations. Not just the failure to reserve, but all these handler specific obligations. They filed false reports. They didn't make raisins available for inspection. There were a whole host of regulatory violations that were at issue here. And when they invoked the handler review action in the district court, they could assert defenses as a handler. But for instance, another producer, producers can't invoke these judicial review schemes. Another producer couldn't have intervened in that action to assert its producer. As this case stands when it, as it comes before us, is there a claim that they, that money, the government is trying to take money from them without just compensation? That was certainly not how we understood the claim to be litigated below. That's not how the ninth circuit thought understood the claim. We've been talking about the claim involving the raisins, which fails for the capacity of reason. Is that an issue we should decide, or is that an issue that the ninth circuit should decide, whether there is a taking claim from money? That was certainly not decided below, so a remand, to the extent that this was preserved, a remand would be possible outcome there

. We think, though, that that claim suffers from separate, separate, well, structural defect. All right. If we assume for the sake of argument that there is such a claim, why does that not fall within AppFell? Well, we think that, for several reasons. First of all, the AppFell opinion that's referred to was just a plurality. It's not been adopted by the Court. Second of all, the AppFell analysis relied on this $1 for $1 for $1 concept. That was a critical part of the plurality's discussion there. And it thought that it would be simply a pointless exercise for Eastern enterprises to be required to pay the premium and then go to the Court of Federal claims and get the exact same amount of money back. Well, don't they claim that there are a whole host of reasons before you leave that? Don't they claim that the entire amount that is assessed against them is taking them? Maybe they're wrong. That the entire amount assessed against them is a taking without just compensation. That's maybe they're wrong, but isn't that a merits question? That's, they are clearly wrong about that. And I, but I think, however you characterize that defect, it defeats this $1 for $1 pointless exercise point. Well, why is that a necessary part of AppFell? Why did an AppFell just meant when we're dealing with cash, you don't have to go to the Court of Claims. So even it, you know, you can have a discussion in the district court about whether it's not $1 for $1 and it should be discounted in some way. But why should the fact that it's $1 for $1 means, why is that a requirement as opposed to just its cash? And so the question of, like, you know, handing some over, handing it all over and getting some back, that can be done in the district court rather than making somebody file a separate suit. Well, I think there were two things going on in AppFell. And there were really two distinct reasons why the plurality in AppFell thought that there was no requirement to go to the Tucker Act there. One was that it thought that in a statute like that that simply allocated benefits and burdens among private entities, Congress would not have intended there to be compensation available in the event that there were a taking. And that was actually the government's position in that case. And the AppFell plurality cited to that portion of the government's brief. And it cited cases in its discussion that weren't $1 for $1 or even cash transfer cases in which the Court had gone to the merits of taking claims without consideration of a Tucker Act remedy. Then there's the second idea, which is the cash transfer idea. And we think that the dollar for dollar aspect of that was important to the plurality's analysis because it viewed that as evidence that Congress would not have intended the Tucker Act to be deployed because it would have been a pointless exercise. So it really went to what Congress's intent was. Here, of course, for myriad reasons, that dollar for dollar analysis breaks out. So, no, but there is a similar, I mean, it seemed to me again, simplifying that underlying this, their clients think this whole raisin program is unconstitutional. What it does is it takes raisins that we grow, in effect, throws them in the river. And in the 30s, that was done to raise raisin prices. And they think as a matter of policy that just hurts people by raising prices and as a matter of constitutional law, it takes raisins from some people that belong to them and uses them for this bad purpose. Okay, that's their view of it. Something like that, isn't it? Yes. Fine. So they're making that kind of constitutional claim. Now, I would think if all you told me was that, and I knew nothing about all these statutes, I would say that's the kind of claim that should be made in a Federal District Court period, not the Court of Claims because their government isn't going to compensate them for anything. That's against the whole point of the program. Either this program is valid or it isn't. And if it isn't, some authoritative set of court should tell us that. So I have a feeling this is somehow not a right fit with the Court of Claims. Now, you explained to me why that purely instinctive feeling at this point is completely wrong. Sure. Justice Breyer, we've now shifted back to the first theory about the property, which is the raisins. What they could have done in 2002, they had been a producer of raisins and solely a producer of raisins for decades. At any point during the, between 1969 and 2002, they could have gone to the Court of Claims and said, this reserve requirement is a taking of my raisins. I want my just compensation. That is not just a remedy as Mr. McConnell suggests. It is a constitutional condition on the taking of private property for public use. As long as there's just compensation, there simply is no violation. So that's why it couldn't be what the statute meant. I think that's what Justice Breyer says. Did Congress create a statute in which we're going to take your raisins and then you can go to the Court of Claims and get your money back. I mean, that surely is not what Congress contemplated. The whole notion of the program is you can't get your money back in the Court of Claims. Now, if you're raising a constitutional objection, that's something else. That should be done in discreet court. But to say that Congress contemplated, you know, we'll take your raisins and then you sue in the Court of Claims and give you your money back. That's a weird statute. Justice Breyer, we have two responses to that

. Okay, that's their view of it. Something like that, isn't it? Yes. Fine. So they're making that kind of constitutional claim. Now, I would think if all you told me was that, and I knew nothing about all these statutes, I would say that's the kind of claim that should be made in a Federal District Court period, not the Court of Claims because their government isn't going to compensate them for anything. That's against the whole point of the program. Either this program is valid or it isn't. And if it isn't, some authoritative set of court should tell us that. So I have a feeling this is somehow not a right fit with the Court of Claims. Now, you explained to me why that purely instinctive feeling at this point is completely wrong. Sure. Justice Breyer, we've now shifted back to the first theory about the property, which is the raisins. What they could have done in 2002, they had been a producer of raisins and solely a producer of raisins for decades. At any point during the, between 1969 and 2002, they could have gone to the Court of Claims and said, this reserve requirement is a taking of my raisins. I want my just compensation. That is not just a remedy as Mr. McConnell suggests. It is a constitutional condition on the taking of private property for public use. As long as there's just compensation, there simply is no violation. So that's why it couldn't be what the statute meant. I think that's what Justice Breyer says. Did Congress create a statute in which we're going to take your raisins and then you can go to the Court of Claims and get your money back. I mean, that surely is not what Congress contemplated. The whole notion of the program is you can't get your money back in the Court of Claims. Now, if you're raising a constitutional objection, that's something else. That should be done in discreet court. But to say that Congress contemplated, you know, we'll take your raisins and then you sue in the Court of Claims and give you your money back. That's a weird statute. Justice Breyer, we have two responses to that. First of all, these claims have been litigated in the Court of Claims. The Evans case, the Kal Almond case, both of which we cite in our brief. Raisin producers, or then the Kal Almond case, it was an Almond producer, went to the Court of Claims and said, this reserve requirement is a taking. I want my money. And they lost the Court of Claims correctly in our view held that there was no taking. That said, we do agree that it is actually a close question whether Congress would have intended compensation to be provided in a situation like this one. In the event the Raisin Reserve program were found to be a taking. We've said in our brief, we do view that as a close question. Although on balance, we think that the proper answer is that there is a remedy, or sorry, there is a just compensation available in the Court of Claims. But there are cases that say that. You think that's a close question? You think that the way the statute is supposed to operate, once it is held that this is an unconstitutional taking, is that every year the government takes the raisins, and every year the grower goes to the Court of Claims and gets the money back for the raisins. Is that the program that Congress anticipated? Well, we do agree that it's a close question for the reason you are. That's a crazy statute. Well, every year we are going to take raisins, and every year we are going to pay you in the Court of Claims. What's the purpose of that? Well, of course, Congress didn't think this was a taking, and it built considerable administrative flexibility into the statute, and at the end of the day, that's what convinces us that Congress would not have intended to preclude compensation in the Court of Claims and to opt for an injunction instead, because the Secretary of Agriculture has wide latitude to adjust. So the conversation wouldn't be paid year after year as your hypotheticals suggested, that program could be adjusted. A reserve requirement is only one way of complying with the kind of supply, control, provisions of the statute. There are any number of options available, but I'd also point out that in this Court's precedent in Monsanto and regional rail, those were both statutory schemes which had their own compensation mechanism. As does this one, this reserve raisins, the producers do get paid sometimes for them in a smaller amount. Those were cases in which the statutes did have compensation mechanisms, and this Court held that the Tucker Act was available as a kind of a supplementary compensation in the event that- Mr. Palmo, am I incorrect in thinking that the government is saying handlers cannot raise the constitutionality of the raised and mocked being order. You told us that the producers can go to the Court of Claims. What about the handlers? They're at least being fined for violating the Act, and it's their position that the whole thing is unconstitutional. Can they raise the constitutionality of the whole arrangement defensively, or they simply can't raise the constitutionality of the Act? Justice Ginsburg, I think this goes back again to the property question. If the claim is that it's unconstitutional because it takes producers' property, they can't raise that in this proceeding. If the property is the raisins, they can't raise that in this proceeding. They need to comply and go to the Court of Claims for compensation, which means there has been no in the event there is a taking, it's a constitutional taking because just compensation is provided. If the claim is that the money that was taken from me, the fine, that itself is a taking, then we think that claim can and must be brought in the context of the AMAA proceeding. That was not how the Court of Appeals understood the claim here to be, and there's a violation of law can be articulated as a taking of the lawbreakers' property without just compensation

. First of all, these claims have been litigated in the Court of Claims. The Evans case, the Kal Almond case, both of which we cite in our brief. Raisin producers, or then the Kal Almond case, it was an Almond producer, went to the Court of Claims and said, this reserve requirement is a taking. I want my money. And they lost the Court of Claims correctly in our view held that there was no taking. That said, we do agree that it is actually a close question whether Congress would have intended compensation to be provided in a situation like this one. In the event the Raisin Reserve program were found to be a taking. We've said in our brief, we do view that as a close question. Although on balance, we think that the proper answer is that there is a remedy, or sorry, there is a just compensation available in the Court of Claims. But there are cases that say that. You think that's a close question? You think that the way the statute is supposed to operate, once it is held that this is an unconstitutional taking, is that every year the government takes the raisins, and every year the grower goes to the Court of Claims and gets the money back for the raisins. Is that the program that Congress anticipated? Well, we do agree that it's a close question for the reason you are. That's a crazy statute. Well, every year we are going to take raisins, and every year we are going to pay you in the Court of Claims. What's the purpose of that? Well, of course, Congress didn't think this was a taking, and it built considerable administrative flexibility into the statute, and at the end of the day, that's what convinces us that Congress would not have intended to preclude compensation in the Court of Claims and to opt for an injunction instead, because the Secretary of Agriculture has wide latitude to adjust. So the conversation wouldn't be paid year after year as your hypotheticals suggested, that program could be adjusted. A reserve requirement is only one way of complying with the kind of supply, control, provisions of the statute. There are any number of options available, but I'd also point out that in this Court's precedent in Monsanto and regional rail, those were both statutory schemes which had their own compensation mechanism. As does this one, this reserve raisins, the producers do get paid sometimes for them in a smaller amount. Those were cases in which the statutes did have compensation mechanisms, and this Court held that the Tucker Act was available as a kind of a supplementary compensation in the event that- Mr. Palmo, am I incorrect in thinking that the government is saying handlers cannot raise the constitutionality of the raised and mocked being order. You told us that the producers can go to the Court of Claims. What about the handlers? They're at least being fined for violating the Act, and it's their position that the whole thing is unconstitutional. Can they raise the constitutionality of the whole arrangement defensively, or they simply can't raise the constitutionality of the Act? Justice Ginsburg, I think this goes back again to the property question. If the claim is that it's unconstitutional because it takes producers' property, they can't raise that in this proceeding. If the property is the raisins, they can't raise that in this proceeding. They need to comply and go to the Court of Claims for compensation, which means there has been no in the event there is a taking, it's a constitutional taking because just compensation is provided. If the claim is that the money that was taken from me, the fine, that itself is a taking, then we think that claim can and must be brought in the context of the AMAA proceeding. That was not how the Court of Appeals understood the claim here to be, and there's a violation of law can be articulated as a taking of the lawbreakers' property without just compensation. I haven't seen any case that stands for that proposition, and that would be very remarkable. But then you just lose on the merits. What the Ninth Circuit says, they can't even argue this. Well, Justice Kennedy, the Ninth Circuit didn't argue that. I thought that what we were going to decide was whether or not, assuming you can go to the Court of Claims, you must go to the Court of Claims. Can you prefer to wait, have a penalty assessed against you, and say this is unconstitutional that it's a taking? Your position is you can't say that. I don't understand why. Other than if you want to talk about Williamson and Soforth, I can get into that. But Justice Kennedy, the Ninth Circuit didn't understand the taking claim to be that the fine for what my violation of law is a taking of my money. That's not how the Ninth Circuit understood the claim, so they didn't analyze it in that way. They understood that the claim to be that the taking of producers' raisins is a taking. And we lawfully resisted it because it was an unconstitutional taking. The Ninth Circuit correctly rejected that because there was nothing unconstitutional about it because it was not without just compensation. The Tucker Act is the just compensation. This Court has held something. Justice, the jumpensation I take it in the program is supposed to come from the fact that raisin prices go up. Well, the poor children with their noses pressed to the glass because they can't pay the raisins. They're parents are the ones who are paying the compensation. And it's certainly not the taxpayer. He's not going to pay. And maybe the other producers will pay some who get jipped or something. I don't know. But I can't believe that Congress wanted the taxpayers to pay for a program that's going to mean they have to pay higher prices as consumers. Just inspiring. That goes to the merits of it. No, no, no, it doesn't go to the merits. It goes to whether or not it makes sense to think that the Court of Claims has something to say about this. And suppose we did this. Suppose we said, given the fact that you filed your thing, whatever it was, you know, laid in the light of this very enlightening discussion, which has been helpful

. I haven't seen any case that stands for that proposition, and that would be very remarkable. But then you just lose on the merits. What the Ninth Circuit says, they can't even argue this. Well, Justice Kennedy, the Ninth Circuit didn't argue that. I thought that what we were going to decide was whether or not, assuming you can go to the Court of Claims, you must go to the Court of Claims. Can you prefer to wait, have a penalty assessed against you, and say this is unconstitutional that it's a taking? Your position is you can't say that. I don't understand why. Other than if you want to talk about Williamson and Soforth, I can get into that. But Justice Kennedy, the Ninth Circuit didn't understand the taking claim to be that the fine for what my violation of law is a taking of my money. That's not how the Ninth Circuit understood the claim, so they didn't analyze it in that way. They understood that the claim to be that the taking of producers' raisins is a taking. And we lawfully resisted it because it was an unconstitutional taking. The Ninth Circuit correctly rejected that because there was nothing unconstitutional about it because it was not without just compensation. The Tucker Act is the just compensation. This Court has held something. Justice, the jumpensation I take it in the program is supposed to come from the fact that raisin prices go up. Well, the poor children with their noses pressed to the glass because they can't pay the raisins. They're parents are the ones who are paying the compensation. And it's certainly not the taxpayer. He's not going to pay. And maybe the other producers will pay some who get jipped or something. I don't know. But I can't believe that Congress wanted the taxpayers to pay for a program that's going to mean they have to pay higher prices as consumers. Just inspiring. That goes to the merits of it. No, no, no, it doesn't go to the merits. It goes to whether or not it makes sense to think that the Court of Claims has something to say about this. And suppose we did this. Suppose we said, given the fact that you filed your thing, whatever it was, you know, laid in the light of this very enlightening discussion, which has been helpful. We think this is the kind of program and challenge to the program where there isn't going to be a remedy really in the Court of Claims. And they ought to go ahead in the ninth circuit and in light of all these enlightening things that will write, you just decide the merits. Is that now? Well, I'm sure you're going to say that absolutely terrible. It won't work at all. So tell me why not. Well, Your Honor, of course, the consequence of that is they reinstate our prior victory in the prior panel opinion. No, no, we'd say we would say, well, given the way that we've talked about the program, perhaps it's best to consider this matter fully. Well, they did consider the matter fully. In the initial opinion, they said there's no taking here. So all of the discussion we're having here is about, is predicated on the idea that if there were a taking, would compensation be available and played? Excuse me. Can I? We agree there's no taking. All right. It almost seems to me, and I'll ask Mr. McConnell when he gets up at Rebuttal, that there is some sort of due process challenge going on here. It's been created by the labels they did in this new business venture. In the normal situation, the handler I'm being told would actually have a title to the raisins, and they would pay the producers for the raisins. So there would be property taking in that situation where the handler is actually owned the property. Would they be able to raise a taking defense? No, because of the way that the statute and the regulatory program works. If the handler is actually buying raisins from the producer, the handler never takes title to the reserve raisins. And he doesn't pay for the reserve raisins. He takes title to the free tonnage raisins, and the title to the reserve raisins passes as a matter of law from the producer to the raisin administrative committee. The handler never owns those raisins. So they are missing a business opportunity because they can't take title to those raisins. And yet you're asking. They would never pay for those raisins because they can't take title. They can't lawfully take title to those. Now this really does sound to me, and I think that both Justice Scalia and Breyer now I'm being more and more convinced. There has to be a place to challenge the scheme. Whether there's a taking's claim for the handler, because the handler is being asked to do things

. We think this is the kind of program and challenge to the program where there isn't going to be a remedy really in the Court of Claims. And they ought to go ahead in the ninth circuit and in light of all these enlightening things that will write, you just decide the merits. Is that now? Well, I'm sure you're going to say that absolutely terrible. It won't work at all. So tell me why not. Well, Your Honor, of course, the consequence of that is they reinstate our prior victory in the prior panel opinion. No, no, we'd say we would say, well, given the way that we've talked about the program, perhaps it's best to consider this matter fully. Well, they did consider the matter fully. In the initial opinion, they said there's no taking here. So all of the discussion we're having here is about, is predicated on the idea that if there were a taking, would compensation be available and played? Excuse me. Can I? We agree there's no taking. All right. It almost seems to me, and I'll ask Mr. McConnell when he gets up at Rebuttal, that there is some sort of due process challenge going on here. It's been created by the labels they did in this new business venture. In the normal situation, the handler I'm being told would actually have a title to the raisins, and they would pay the producers for the raisins. So there would be property taking in that situation where the handler is actually owned the property. Would they be able to raise a taking defense? No, because of the way that the statute and the regulatory program works. If the handler is actually buying raisins from the producer, the handler never takes title to the reserve raisins. And he doesn't pay for the reserve raisins. He takes title to the free tonnage raisins, and the title to the reserve raisins passes as a matter of law from the producer to the raisin administrative committee. The handler never owns those raisins. So they are missing a business opportunity because they can't take title to those raisins. And yet you're asking. They would never pay for those raisins because they can't take title. They can't lawfully take title to those. Now this really does sound to me, and I think that both Justice Scalia and Breyer now I'm being more and more convinced. There has to be a place to challenge the scheme. Whether there's a taking's claim for the handler, because the handler is being asked to do things. But the handler's property is not being taken, and that's critical. There are separate taking's claims that handlers have advanced, that could be asserted through this process. For instance, there was a case called Lyon raisins from the Federal Circuit that we cite in our brief, in which the issue was that the handler provided bins to store the raisins, and he didn't get his bins back. That was a handler taking the claim, and that had to be asserted in the context of this handler review scheme. But the handler doesn't own the raisins under this scheme. That's a marriage question again. I mean, it's not a question of whether you can resist on the basis of the taking's claim. It's a question of whether you're going to win. Now Justice Scalia, I think it goes to the scope, the capacity question that we were talking about before, because the statute is quite clear in Section 608C-13B that this scheme does not regulate producers in their capacity as producers. And if someone wants to take on both roles, they will be regulated only as a handler. So the regulatory obligations that apply to petitioners when they adopted this business model, or handler only regulatory obligations, and then this is a handler judicial review proceeding. It's a very narrow means of decision here that avoids some of these kind of conceptual questions about the nature of the taking's clause, which is that this claim simply doesn't belong in this proceeding. But there's no unfairness or no due process issue here at all, because they, in 2002, when petitioners decided to engage in this, these regulatory violations in order to secure an unfair advantage over their competitors, as was found by the ALJA at JAA-41. At that point, they could have sought compensation for the past six years of raisins that they had provided. They didn't do it. I don't understand why they didn't do it. They left that claim on the table. And to the extent they wanted to claim going forward, they could have continued to use compliant handlers and sued every month for compensation in the Court of Claims. Did I understand you to say a couple of minutes ago that if the case were remanded, you would be entitled to win on the reasoning of the panel opinion? The prior panel opinion. If there was a remand on the basis that the Ninth Circuit misunderstood this as a jurisdictional Article III defect, and then the Ninth Circuit were to find waiver, what the Ninth Circuit presumably would do would be reinstate its first panel decision, which we think was also correct and held that there was no taking here. There it is. So, Mr. Palmore, what would be wrong? Would anything be wrong with a disposition of this Court that went something like this? Everybody agrees that this is not a jurisdictional issue, including the government, so they got that wrong. Now, as to this whole business about the Tucker Act and whether the Tucker Act provides a remedy, the government only started talking about that in a petition for re-hearing on-bunk, and the government can't do that. You know, it can't introduce an argument like this in a petition for re-hearing on-bunk, so that's waived. And now, the Ninth Circuit can go and try to figure out whether this marketing order is a taking or is just the world's most outdated law. That would certainly be an available option, or the Ninth Circuit could decide for itself whether there had been a waiver. But there's a separate issue, and there's this capacity issue, which is a separate point that the Ninth Circuit made at GA305 when it pointed out that this was a producer claim, and that's something that was strictly a producer claim, and it wasn't a fit for this handler review, actually, and that's something that could also be considered on remand. But the consequence of this would be for the Court to impose if it found a waiver to rule for us for separate merits reasons

. But the handler's property is not being taken, and that's critical. There are separate taking's claims that handlers have advanced, that could be asserted through this process. For instance, there was a case called Lyon raisins from the Federal Circuit that we cite in our brief, in which the issue was that the handler provided bins to store the raisins, and he didn't get his bins back. That was a handler taking the claim, and that had to be asserted in the context of this handler review scheme. But the handler doesn't own the raisins under this scheme. That's a marriage question again. I mean, it's not a question of whether you can resist on the basis of the taking's claim. It's a question of whether you're going to win. Now Justice Scalia, I think it goes to the scope, the capacity question that we were talking about before, because the statute is quite clear in Section 608C-13B that this scheme does not regulate producers in their capacity as producers. And if someone wants to take on both roles, they will be regulated only as a handler. So the regulatory obligations that apply to petitioners when they adopted this business model, or handler only regulatory obligations, and then this is a handler judicial review proceeding. It's a very narrow means of decision here that avoids some of these kind of conceptual questions about the nature of the taking's clause, which is that this claim simply doesn't belong in this proceeding. But there's no unfairness or no due process issue here at all, because they, in 2002, when petitioners decided to engage in this, these regulatory violations in order to secure an unfair advantage over their competitors, as was found by the ALJA at JAA-41. At that point, they could have sought compensation for the past six years of raisins that they had provided. They didn't do it. I don't understand why they didn't do it. They left that claim on the table. And to the extent they wanted to claim going forward, they could have continued to use compliant handlers and sued every month for compensation in the Court of Claims. Did I understand you to say a couple of minutes ago that if the case were remanded, you would be entitled to win on the reasoning of the panel opinion? The prior panel opinion. If there was a remand on the basis that the Ninth Circuit misunderstood this as a jurisdictional Article III defect, and then the Ninth Circuit were to find waiver, what the Ninth Circuit presumably would do would be reinstate its first panel decision, which we think was also correct and held that there was no taking here. There it is. So, Mr. Palmore, what would be wrong? Would anything be wrong with a disposition of this Court that went something like this? Everybody agrees that this is not a jurisdictional issue, including the government, so they got that wrong. Now, as to this whole business about the Tucker Act and whether the Tucker Act provides a remedy, the government only started talking about that in a petition for re-hearing on-bunk, and the government can't do that. You know, it can't introduce an argument like this in a petition for re-hearing on-bunk, so that's waived. And now, the Ninth Circuit can go and try to figure out whether this marketing order is a taking or is just the world's most outdated law. That would certainly be an available option, or the Ninth Circuit could decide for itself whether there had been a waiver. But there's a separate issue, and there's this capacity issue, which is a separate point that the Ninth Circuit made at GA305 when it pointed out that this was a producer claim, and that's something that was strictly a producer claim, and it wasn't a fit for this handler review, actually, and that's something that could also be considered on remand. But the consequence of this would be for the Court to impose if it found a waiver to rule for us for separate merits reasons. We do view the Tucker Act, the failure to seek just compensation as a merits defect in the petitioner's claim here. So even putting this capacity problem aside, there's simply no defense. Mr. McConnell says that this can be raised as a defense, but there is no defense. If all you show is that there has been a taking of private property for public reasons. What is the whole stop? There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. On the regulatory scheme. That petitioners were handlers. And in fact, there is a surprisingly, I just wanted to look at the word acquire. A choir is defined to include a number of things, including to possess. And a handler is anyone who sells raisins. There was no mystery about this, and in fact, it pages 8 through 11 of our brief. We cite communication after communication where U.S. So that sounds like a good time. Yes, it can. It can. It can. It can

. We do view the Tucker Act, the failure to seek just compensation as a merits defect in the petitioner's claim here. So even putting this capacity problem aside, there's simply no defense. Mr. McConnell says that this can be raised as a defense, but there is no defense. If all you show is that there has been a taking of private property for public reasons. What is the whole stop? There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. There is no. On the regulatory scheme. That petitioners were handlers. And in fact, there is a surprisingly, I just wanted to look at the word acquire. A choir is defined to include a number of things, including to possess. And a handler is anyone who sells raisins. There was no mystery about this, and in fact, it pages 8 through 11 of our brief. We cite communication after communication where U.S. So that sounds like a good time. Yes, it can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. I have a number of read to talk about, pretty ничего to talk about, this isn't very high. that there could be a recommendation on Point D. So there was, I was, sort of primarily in one decree in a rest sermon. And there were cases like this in an evaluation lake. that claim at every level twice within the Department of Agriculture in the District Court and the Court of Appeals. They lost on that regulatory claim. This wasn't a good faith misunderstanding. If you look at JAA-41, the ALJ found that this was a willful and intentional knowing violation of regulatory requirements because they were able to undercut their competitors by not playing by the rules. So this doesn't present any kind of due process. No, but still then they might, if there are acquires. They are acquires, okay? They think this program is unconstitutional because it takes some other people's property. Right? So those other people are in a very special relation to them. Those other people are really close. And it may be they have standing to assert those other people's claims. And if they do have standing to assert those other people's claims, why can't they make the argument that way? I disagree that they have standing to make those other people's claims. And also Petitius haven't argued, haven't made any third-party standing argument here. But this Court's requirements are quite strict for third-party standing. You have to have a close relationship. And I don't think a mere arms length commercial relationship would have

. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. It can. I have a number of read to talk about, pretty ничего to talk about, this isn't very high. that there could be a recommendation on Point D. So there was, I was, sort of primarily in one decree in a rest sermon. And there were cases like this in an evaluation lake. that claim at every level twice within the Department of Agriculture in the District Court and the Court of Appeals. They lost on that regulatory claim. This wasn't a good faith misunderstanding. If you look at JAA-41, the ALJ found that this was a willful and intentional knowing violation of regulatory requirements because they were able to undercut their competitors by not playing by the rules. So this doesn't present any kind of due process. No, but still then they might, if there are acquires. They are acquires, okay? They think this program is unconstitutional because it takes some other people's property. Right? So those other people are in a very special relation to them. Those other people are really close. And it may be they have standing to assert those other people's claims. And if they do have standing to assert those other people's claims, why can't they make the argument that way? I disagree that they have standing to make those other people's claims. And also Petitius haven't argued, haven't made any third-party standing argument here. But this Court's requirements are quite strict for third-party standing. You have to have a close relationship. And I don't think a mere arms length commercial relationship would have. How have standing, could they raise the claim? If you say no. Well, they certainly have standing as producers to raise the claim. That's the sum they have standing, could they raise the claim? Yes. That this is an unconstitutional taking. In the Court of Claims, absolutely. As per noes. No. In the administrative proceeding, where there are charges, where there are penalties being assessed against them. I think that they would have standing, but it's still a claim that's beyond the scope of this narrow, specific judicial review proceeding. I think it's a different problem. I have to say, I think it comes with less than good grace for you to criticize the other side for not having raised a particular argument. But I do want to clarify that you have no objection at this point for reversing the Ninth Circuit on the ground that they aired and saying that this should have dismissed on jurisdictional grounds. Well, I'm not going to resist that too strenuously. I'm not, but I think if they did decide the question, they decided it correctly. It was a threshold defect. Their analysis was all correct. So I think that's before the Court. But yes, we frankly acknowledge and we acknowledged in our brief that we did not. We did suggest below that this was a jurisdictional defect. Ninth Circuit Authority said that it was, and we relied on that. We now believe that it's best understood not as a jurisdictional defect, but as a substantive defect in the claims. Not simply a choice of remedies as you, as Petitioner suggested, because choice of remedies suggests that there's been a constitutional wrong, and then we need to decide what remedy is going to be available in a function or damages. The short answer is, yes, reach the merits only if I win. That's really what you want us to do. Well, do we think you can reach some of the merits? We think that the narrow disposition here is the capacity to ask you this question, because do you want us to reach the merits if we're going to have you lose? You got to want one or the other. Do you want us to reach the merits? Period is really the question. Yeah, our position is that we're not acquiescing in a remand. We think you can affirm, and you should affirm. No

. How have standing, could they raise the claim? If you say no. Well, they certainly have standing as producers to raise the claim. That's the sum they have standing, could they raise the claim? Yes. That this is an unconstitutional taking. In the Court of Claims, absolutely. As per noes. No. In the administrative proceeding, where there are charges, where there are penalties being assessed against them. I think that they would have standing, but it's still a claim that's beyond the scope of this narrow, specific judicial review proceeding. I think it's a different problem. I have to say, I think it comes with less than good grace for you to criticize the other side for not having raised a particular argument. But I do want to clarify that you have no objection at this point for reversing the Ninth Circuit on the ground that they aired and saying that this should have dismissed on jurisdictional grounds. Well, I'm not going to resist that too strenuously. I'm not, but I think if they did decide the question, they decided it correctly. It was a threshold defect. Their analysis was all correct. So I think that's before the Court. But yes, we frankly acknowledge and we acknowledged in our brief that we did not. We did suggest below that this was a jurisdictional defect. Ninth Circuit Authority said that it was, and we relied on that. We now believe that it's best understood not as a jurisdictional defect, but as a substantive defect in the claims. Not simply a choice of remedies as you, as Petitioner suggested, because choice of remedies suggests that there's been a constitutional wrong, and then we need to decide what remedy is going to be available in a function or damages. The short answer is, yes, reach the merits only if I win. That's really what you want us to do. Well, do we think you can reach some of the merits? We think that the narrow disposition here is the capacity to ask you this question, because do you want us to reach the merits if we're going to have you lose? You got to want one or the other. Do you want us to reach the merits? Period is really the question. Yeah, our position is that we're not acquiescing in a remand. We think you can affirm, and you should affirm. No. However, I do recognize. Do you think we should reach the merits, which is a very different question? Well, it depends on what you mean by merits. Okay. Only if you win. There's the undertaking, no. There's the underlying kind of takings claim that there was, was there a taking here at all, and that's not before the court. I don't think anyone suggests that that's before the court. But we do think that there are a series of other threshold defects in the claim that this court could rely on. Thank you, Mr. Palmore. Mr. McConnell, you have three minutes remaining. I'd like to make two quick points. One is that I believe that the government has essentially conceded here in this argument, and in their brief, that the Tucker Act does not apply. They have told us that the Tucker Act does not apply in page 50 and repeated here when Congress could not have contemplated a compensation. Now, in a debt, and their only answer to that is to say, first, the Congress didn't think it would be a taking, which in regional rail, this Court said, is not the question. And secondly, that if there's one, we should get paid once, compensation, once, and then the administrator is going to cancel the program, which is no answer at all. Either the statute contemplates compensation for everybody or it contemplates it for nobody, I think they have effectively conceded that the Tucker Act does not apply. Well, they've conceded that it doesn't apply to handlers. Two handlers. And in my opinion, the fact that there is a second issue I wanted to talk about is this capacity issue. Certainly, we have standing, it's not third-party standing, all of the money comes out of our pocket. Yes, we have standing. And secondly, we certainly, and then that is in our capacity as handler, essentially the Department of Agriculture's view, is that during those couple of days when the raisins are going through our packing plant, that we acquired them and possessed them during those couple of days, and that we should have given them their share. That's raisins, that's not money, but by the time they get around to enforcing that and so forth, the raisins are gone, and now the money stands in for the raisins. But that is a taking claim. We think it's a straightforward taking claim under Norwood and Missouri Pacific Railroad. That's a merits question, but in any event, it is not a problem of capacity. Whatever might be that taking, that taking is in the capacity as a handler

. Those are my two points. Thank you. Thank you, Council. The case is submitted



hat lasts. Why isn't it for them to make that argument? Because you know, you're better off, et cetera. If you would look at the, is it a way to do that? I mean, what's the, what's the, no, it's the regulation. I'm, I'm sorry, if you look at 7 CFR 989.166C, you will see that that is the provision for what happens when the handler does not turn over reserve raisins to the Department of Agriculture. It is, it has very specific provisions for what happens, and there is no provision in that for implicit and kind compensation. But just, can they argue that, the fact that all the raisin producers are better off because of this program, including you, but no free riders. That's what's the compensation. Can they at least argue that, or if they conceded that? Under this regulation, I do not think it is open to the Department of Agriculture to argue that. I think that that would be a logical argument if this were an imminent domain proceeding, and we were simply trying to figure out what the proper value of the raisins is. Reserving, of course, the point that we believe that this program does not benefit the producer. We believe that the, we believe that this program actually makes the producers demonstrably worse off. The only people who benefit from this program are the recipients of the subsidy, of the export subsidies. The export is, that's right. Mr. Montgomery, why take you back to the very first thing that you said in this argument? Because you said, typically, the handler doesn't take the product, and the handler doesn't pay for the product. And you would think that the horns here would only have a takings claim, assuming that they do have a takings claim for the raisins that they produced, and not for the raisins that other people produced. But you said that that's not correct in this case? It is not, because they pay the, they, a check went out from the Raisin Marketing Association to the producers for every raisin, not just the free tonnage raisins, but for the reserve tonnage raisins as well. So the horns are actually the only people with a financial interest in the raisins in this case. That is unusual. Mr. McConaughey, this is probably neither here nor there, but what is the impact of the drought been on the raisin producers? Do you know? It is not good. It's very carefully guarded respite. And I wonder, I wonder if I'll be able to take a shower when I go on. Thank you, counsel. The case is submitted.

We'll get an argument this morning in case 14275, foreign versus Department of Agriculture. Mr. McConnell? Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the Court. Thank you for being willing to hear this little case the second time. It does involve some important principles and the livelihoods of Marvin and Laura Horn and more indirectly hundreds of small California raisin growers will be profoundly affected. This is an administrative enforcement proceeding that was brought by the Department of Agriculture against my clients, commanding the relinquishment of funds connected to specific pieces of property, namely reserved kind of raisins. My clients appear in their capacity as handlers, but under their particular facts of this case, the economic circumstances are somewhat different than are ordinarily true in this industry, because as handlers, the horns actually assumed the full financial responsibility for the raisins that were not turned over to the Department of Agriculture. The producers in this case were fully paid for their raisins. This is a factual finding to be found in the judicial officers' opinion at 66A of the appendix to the petition. The horns paid the producers for their raisins, according to the judicial officer, those raisins became part of the inventory of the horns. The, when the Raisin Administrative Committee, which I'll refer to as the RAC, came after the raisins. It was the horns and the horns only who bore the economic burden of this taking. I thought the growers were paid only for the volume that they were permitted, that was permitted, the permitted volume, and that they were not paid for what goes in the reserve pool. Justice Ginsburg, that is true in the ordinary course that was not true in this particular case because of the unusual business model of my clients. These producers were paid the for all of their raisins. Sotomayor, do you objecting to the volume limitation or is it just that the reserve pool that you find? We believe that a volume limitation would be a use restriction that might possibly be challengeable under the pencentral test, but it would not be a per se taking. In this case, because the government, the RAC, which is an agent of the Department of Agriculture, actually takes possession, ownership of the raisins, it is that aspect of the case, which we're challenging. So, because if you're not challenging the volume itself, you can't sell more than 60% of your crop. That's correct. And what happens to the rest of it? We're not going to be able to feed your family on the rest of the 40%. In the ordinary case, the reserve percentage, which in one case was 37%, and was 30% in the other case, 47% is handed over to the raisin administrative committee. But if it wasn't, if we just had a volume, you cannot sell more than X amount. Then I take it that the grow would get nothing, nothing at all, at least with this reserve pool, there is the possibility of getting some money. Well, it all depends. The way volume controls generally work is the owner of the produce is permitted. They have to hold back a certain amount in a reserve, and then they're permitted to sell that reserve as the market conditions continue. In this case, of course, the RAC, a sold the raisins, in some cases, even above the field price. There was a market for the raisins, so I would assume that volume controls under these economic conditions might have left these particular people better off than under the current. So what you're complaining about is the administrative expenses? I still don't understand why this makes this a pen central case, as opposed to a per se taking. You've given up on this being a pen central case. We have never claimed that there was a pen central case. So basically you see an excess between the regulation and its purpose. We do, but more fundamentally, this is an actual transfer of the raisins themselves to the government. How is this different than Leonard? Well, Leonard involved oyster shells, which are owned by the state, their wild animals, they're the property of the state, and the oyster men had no property interest in them, other than what the state chose to license them to harvest. Oh, is that really true, Mr. McConnell? I mean, when these fishermen took the oysters, the oysters, you know, including the shells from the day or other waters, you know, they could then sell the oysters. Why weren't the oyster shells there, is at that point? They have whatever property interests the state of Maryland provided for them in the state of Maryland withheld the 10 percent of the oyster shells for the purpose of essentially fertilizing the oyster. I mean, I guess I would have thought that as soon as they bring the oysters out of the bay, and they haul their catch to shore, that what they've hauled to shore is then theirs. Except for the 10 percent that the state reserved, yes. Well, so I guess what Justice Sotomayor's question is, is why wouldn't the same be true as to raisins? Because raisins are not wild animals, even if they're dancing, and they did not originally belong to the federal government. So you think that Leonard is an animal's case, as opposed to a, you know, the state contacts your property case? Yes, I do. That's not how I'm just saying. I have a court. They called it a tax? They did also call it a tax, and I'm perfectly happy to address whether this is a tax because under this court's standards for criteria for determining a tax. This certainly is not one. We're referring to the criteria and the NFIB case. This is not in the internal revenue code. It's not collected by the internal revenue service. It's not authored. There's no tax authorized by Congress. The proceeds of the tax do not go into the general treasury. No, it did not. But it didn't happen that way, and Leonard either. The court was basically saying is the government could do this because this is a good in commerce. As long as it could meet the pen central test, that there is some nexus between the government's goal and the regulation. Then it's okay. Now, they're used to to fertilize oyster ponds, order to refurtilize the oysters. Here, they're doing it to maintain prices and giving you whatever is left over on the reserve. The fact of the matters of the oysters belonged to the state of Maryland. And when the state of Maryland decides to allow fishermen to harvest the oysters. Could you tell me where, in Leonard, was discussed? It's the, I'm very happy to file a supplemental brief with the Maryland citations indicating that the oysters belonged to the state of Maryland. I thought that the, what the Constitution required for a taking was just compensation, but not a reasonable nexus to a good policy. I remember wrong about that. So, I suppose that question. I underline the government's briefs. And we can ask them what its position is. Are you can characterize their position as if you choose. Is the thing, since we could do this, other ways, what difference does it make? Do you understand that to be there, an underlying premise in their argument? Or is that unfair on my part? Well, they certainly say that from time to time in this court two years ago, in Coons rejected arguments of that sort. But in fact, there is a fundamental difference between a volume control, which is present for a number of our agricultural products versus the taking, because in this case, the government literally takes possession of the raisins. It can use the raisins as collateral to get alone. It can give the raisins away. It can sell the raisins. Mrs. In, why didn't you ask your talking, this reserve arrangement, and the possession, the government's possession of the raisins themselves? And as far as I've heard so far, you are not attacking volume limit. You cannot mark it more than X amount. Marking to then ask the Department of Agriculture for an exemption from the reserve pool. Instead of, you're trying to do now, is to get rid of the volume limit as well. In this particular program, there is no separate volume control in the sense that there's no regulation that tells either producers or handlers how to use or sell raisins. Instead, they're told to set aside the raisins and give them to the government. So here there is a taking. But the part that isn't given to the government, suppose we just, including you have asked to excise that part of it and still leave the limit on the amount that could be marketed. I mean, does it behave a division between what goes in the reserve and what can be marketed? Well, just as Ginsburg, the way this case arose is the Department of Agriculture came after my clients. We did not, this is not our lawsuit. The Department came after our clients. Is it counterclaim? It's a defense. It's a defense. The Department says, give us either raisins or their monetary equivalent. And we say that's not constitutional. If there was a taking, would there be any obligation on your part to propose an alternative to the taking? The government comes and takes your property. Can't you just resist the taking without saying, oh, government, you can do this in another way. Please do it in a different way. You don't have to do that to you. We do not. And I'm not sure that any alternative ways would even be permitted under the regulations. So my question is, it goes on from this. I mean, maybe the answer is we'll just don't decide that. But I assume with you for the moment, for arguments say, I have some raisins. In my basement, I'm in this program. The government comes with a shovel and some burlap sacks. It takes the raisins. I would say, well, it sounds like a taking to me. At the next point, the Constitution doesn't forbid taking. It says what you have to do is pay just compensation. Now, it's at that point I want to know what happens because I guess the government could argue, look at this program. It's a big program. This program, what it does is it gives raisin farmers at the public's expense more money. So if, in fact, you don't want us to take your raisins, all right, fine. But there would be no program if everybody said that. So we have a rule against free riders. Now, we'll give you what it costs you to take your raisins. What it costs you is, in fact, the difference between what you receive given the program and what you would receive without the program. That difference works in your favor. It gives you money. It doesn't take money. So there is no compensation, too. In fact, if we were to have compensation, you should pay us the government. So how are you going to get by that part? And if you can't get by that part, how are you going to avoid paying the fine? See, I don't see the relation between the taking argument, which is maybe all we have to decide. And how eventually you either get some money or you don't have to pay the fine. If you have a minute, I'd appreciate just the explanation. I would love to. There's both a conceptual and a practical response. Let me give the practical response first, which is that my clients are certainly not better off. By the Secretary's own calculation, the price of raisins was $63 per tonne higher with the volume controls than it would have been in an unregulated market. The fuel price that year was $810 per tonne, taking away 30 percent of their raisins, does not end up with the, with my clients, better off as a result of the program, quite the contrary. They lose money. We have the calculation in our... I don't want to interrupt. You're going to get to the theoretical argument, but isn't the response that, well, the price that you just quoted is because of this program. And that's circular. Or am I wrong? No, no. The Secretary's own calculations, $63 of that $810 is attributable to the volume controls in the program, only $63. Except I were, we told that the demand for raisins is inelastic. So if you glut the market, you're going to have what happened before the RCA. Well, it's... You're going to have... Probably, it's dropping. It is... That's the purpose of free competition, isn't it? Actually, under today's conditions, the elasticity is not as enormous as it would need to be for this to be a proper form. Well, that's today, but you haven't paid a reserve in years now. Well, we're talking... I'm when I say today what I mean is the... One of your orders... I guess it's... No, the conceptual point is that this is a per se taking. And it's... If there were benefits, such as, I don't believe that there were, if there were, that would at most go to whether there was implicit in-kind compensation for the taking, which would go to the question of compensation. Yeah. Implicit in-kind compensation is a complicated matter. It has to do with whether there were special benefits, that there's a split all over the country on that. I don't think we want to get into whether this would be a special benefit. Okay, so what we should say is... You have any objection to my writing if I were to write it like this. Taking. Yeah, it's a taking. Okay. But the Constitution forbids taking without compensation. The object of the program is at least in general to give farmers more compensation than they would have without it. Programs can work badly. Sometimes they're counterproductive. But if this is working well, that's what happens. So we send it back to the Court to see, did the program work well? Did it work to actually make your client better off? What rules do we follow? That's how we should do this in Europe and... I think not. Now, if I... But I'm close to there. If this were an imminent domain proceeding, then the lower court would determine whether there was implicit in-kind contribution. If it were an inverse compensation proceeding, possibly the same. But this is actually an enforcement action. It is specifically guided by the regulations in the seven CFR. And under those regulations, we know exactly what takes place. And implicit in-kind contribution is not provided for in those regulations. What is provided in those regulations is that the if reserve pool raisins are not handed over to the RAC, the handler must pay, multiply the number of raisins by the field price, and that is it. Now, that is also the measure of the value of the raisins, so that if they take that, the compensation is exactly that, and the two things simpler are washed, because the regulation... And I think the broader principle here is that this is actually not a program which is designed to provide compensation. The government almost concedes this. This is not like getting land for a post office, where the government intends to pay. This is more like a program like Kaiser etna, or some of the others, where if it is a taking, the government has no intention of paying a compensation. That is not the kind of program it is. In cases where there is a taking, and the program does not contemplate compensation, the standard judicial remedy for that is to forbid the taking. So, is there anything else that Mr. McConnell to the, whether it is a taking point? And I've just been trying to think about whether your argument would apply to other kinds of programs, and how it might apply to other kinds of programs. So, how about just programs where the government says, give us produce records for us? I'm sure that there are a lot of programs like that in the world. And there is something intuitive about your saying, well, the government is asking us to turn over stuff. And I'm wondering, it seems to me that the government asks people to turn over stuff all the time in the form of records. How would that fair under your argument? Well, if the records, if what the government is asking for is information, this is not going to be a taking. If the records are themselves of historical value as they were in Nixon versus all services of the administration, and they want to put them in the museum, and have their historical value, they're just physical objects. In the same way, the raisins are physical objects, and the government wants some records. The government does not take permanent possession of records. If I'm saying an IRS audit and they ask me to show records to establish my tax deductions, I show them the records, they see the information, it is not a taking. No, but so you're saying that the government couldn't ask you to deliver records to them? I did not say that. They can ask me to do that, and it is not a taking unless they've taken a sort of permanent possessory interest. If they go off and sell the records, the way they sell the raisins, then I... They're just keeping the records. They're keeping the records. If they're keeping the records forever, I am not sure, but I doubt very much that that would be a taking. Again, the value of the records is the information, which is what I assume it is in a regulatory program. We're not talking about actual physical... Well, there are cases on custodial legas, the government all the time, in criminal cases, takes control of valuable objects for evidence, and sometimes it keeps it forever and ever, and in those cases I think there is a taking if it's too long. I think we said that, or I think other courts have said that. I know there was the government can keep it only so long as it's reasonably necessary for the case. You have a valuable diamond ring, which is evidence, and the government keeps it. But it keeps it only for so long as... I think that their complicated sets of rules have been to a contraband and have to do with property that is used as an instrumentality of a crime, and so forth. But this is extremely far afield from raisins, which are a valuable piece of property. If you've tried that, you've seen cells. I guess I'm trying to understand why it's far afield, and what it's far afield from. I mean, you even said, well, information is no problem, but people have property interests and information all the time. And if the government says you have to give us that information, which counts as property, why is that not subject to your rule? Information can be property when it's intellectual property. For example, trade secrets can be property. I don't think ordinary records such as the IRS demands from taxpayers as a taking. It's not to okay. Where we said the turning over of trade secrets, which is property, you've just admitted that, for the privilege of selling other commodities, the pesticides, was okay. Wasn't it taking? How do you deal with that case? There's broad language in that case, which this Court cut back upon in Nolan v. California Coastal Commission. In Nolan, the Court held that Monsanto could not stand for the proposition that it is an affirmative benefit to someone simply to allow them to use their property in an ordinary sense. There has to be an actual affirmative government grant of a benefit for the condition of the Court. Getting 63 per work. Getting 63 dollars more pounds for what you sell seems like a significant benefit. They're not given the 63 dollars results from volume controls. That does not require a taking. The taking itself is of absolutely no value to the producers or anyone else other than those who receive the export subsidies from the sale of the raisins. They're the only ones who benefit from the actual take. But you couldn't do it. You would have a product that would be value less except for that what you could eat at home. But you didn't intend to eat at home because you gave it up for sale. If they gave you the raisins, would you be able to export them and get the government subsidy? If they, my clients are not actually in the export business. If my clients were selling raisins for export, they would be entitled to receive the export subsidy. But that's not the business that they're in. My point is, you couldn't otherwise sell this commodity. If all they did was put it in the house and say to the producers, sell 60 percent this year. What would you do with the raisins? Well, the way they got out of the way other programs of volume controls work is that there's an initial reserve. And then as market conditions develop and more information is available, the owners of the product are permitted to release more and more into the market. And in these particular. That's a particular product, though, the other way. Well, that would be a different case. And then if it went completely the other way, it could well be that the owners of the raisins receive no money at all. But it's still a restriction on their use. The raisins haven't been taken from them. In this case, the raisins are actually taken from them. And the government sells them. In fact, in one of these years, the government was able to sell the raisins for more than the field. It's still the curly queue on this. I've helped a lot in my thinking. But there's still what we do about this fine. And the reason that I'm maybe just a curly queue on the case. But the way I'm thinking of it, imaginary plan, I don't think I'll ask it. I'll figure it out myself. I want you to reserve it. Thank you. If there are no further questions, I'll reserve the remainder of my time for a bottle. Thank you, counsel. Mr. Needer? Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the court. Petitioners isolate just one feature of a comprehensive program regulating the commercial marketing of a fungible agricultural product. A regulatory program that was established with producer approval and is established for their benefit. It is a cooperative program among the secretary, producers, and handlers. The raisins are not put into the program for the benefit of the government. They are put into the program for the benefit of producers. And they enter this stream of commerce. In fact, a producer is affected by this program. These plaintiffs are ingrates, right? You're really helping them. That's for their benefit. And they wanted this, didn't they? These petitioners do not want the program, but the program was established on the premise that it is for the benefit of the government. It's one little feature of an overall program. That little feature happens to be the taking of raisins. You can have a lot of features. There's no objection to having many features. But where one of them is a taking, you have to justify it by just compensation. The question is whether it is a taking and we believe it is not. You used to say it's not a taking if it involves just personal property. Only real estate. Are you still? The government has abandoned that. That has not been our position. We have not argued that personal property is not subject to the just compensation clause. Such that if the government came in and took someone's car or someone's race. Well, the government has not taken the right. Let me just, if I could set this up and explain how it operates. This program operates only when the producer, the grower, has voluntarily submitted committed the raisins to the stream of commerce. They have been put into the stream of commerce. They are turned over to the handler. The marketing order regulates only the conduct of handlers. The government can prevent you from putting something into the stream of commerce. Can charge you for putting something into the stream? I think the government can attach reasonable conditions on entering a stream of commerce. Including that taking. That I think is the lesson of Monts Ambrel, which I think is a more constitutional condition, isn't it? No, in England, out just compensation would be an unconstitutional condition for putting something into the stream of commerce. That analysis would apply if there was a taking on the Northern Dolan analogy, for example. Is there any limit to that argument? There are some examples in the briefs that are pretty startling. The government said it was a manufacturer of cell phones. You can sell cell phones. However, every fifth one you have to give to us. Or a manufacturer of cars. You can sell cars in the United States. But every third car you have to give to the United States. I think that would present a very different question. Why would it be to... Why would it be to... Because this is part of a comprehensive regulatory program that it isn't just acquiring it to the system. So you say if the government took all GM's cars, then it would be okay. No. But just not a third. No, no. We are not saying that at all. But just before you do. I mean, the rationale... I mean, the government can come up with a rationale to justify those examples really easily. You say cell phone providers benefit greatly if there's a broader cell phone market. If more people are using them. So we're going to take every fifth one and give it to people who might otherwise not be able to afford a cell phone. And that will help cell phone manufacturers. Because more and more people will have them. More and more people will want them. Therefore, it's okay. That's the same rationale you're applying here. This is for the good of the people whose property were taken. Well, these programs go back to the 1930s when the agricultural industry in this country. It was in serious trouble. And particularly in California, prices were below costs of production. And you can do what you've done in most other marketing orders, which is not take their raisins. Instead, say, look, you can only plant 63% of your acreage this year. Or you can only produce 28 tons. That's how most of them work. And most of them, thereby, I presume, analyzed under Penn Central. This is different. This is different because you come up with the truck and you get the shovels and you take their raisins. Probably in the dark of night. No. That is not what the government does. The way the order operates is that the producer submits the raisins to the handler, the handler then divides them into two categories. The handler is required by the order to maintain and separate the reserve raisins. But they are separated for later sale. They don't go to the government. They don't, they are separated for later sale. The proceeds are. What do you mean they don't go to the, does not the government own them? Do you deny that the government owns them? For these purposes, for purposes of this case, we can see that the government gets legal title. But that doesn't mean that the government has the entire interest in the raisins. The government has legal titles so that it may, we will assume, for purposes of this case. So that that the government can, or the committee, it's not the Secretary of Agriculture, the committee can then sell the raisins that proceeds of those sales are pulled and distributed back to the producers. How many, how many, how much from those sales did these petitioners acquire in the two years at issue here? Well, in how much, how much money was given back to them? In one year there was $272 per ton. And the other year there was, there were no proceeds back because the cost of administering the reserve program exceeded, there was no net proceeds afterwards. So over the history of the program, it starts in 1949, right? Yes. And so in how many years model the program as an effect? Was there a distribution to the growers? I do not know that how many years, but a great number of years, and in fact the three years leading up to this particular time, one of the years here was $47 million was returned. In the prior years, it was $50 million and another $30 million. So the experience has been, that there typically has been a loss of time. I need to, I too am troubled like Justice Alito about his free fifth telephone or whatever, every fifth car or every fifth telephone you have to give to the government. You, I don't know you've answered that question. Is that a taking or isn't it? And, and once the basis, not distinguish it from, because this is a comprehensive governmental program. And, and it, it, it governs quality, it governs timing of sales, and it's important to recognize that's all that is going on here. The reserve raisins are set aside by the handler after the producer has voluntarily turned them over. They're set aside by the handler for later sale. Petitioners can see it in their brief at page 23 that the government can regulate the when, the manner, and the channel of sales. That's exactly what the reserve program does. They're turned over to the handler. The handler sets them aside and reserve. Mr. Hitler, he's end of sides when and where to sell them. This, this is a historical quirk that you have to defend. You could achieve your, the government's objectives, just as you do in most other cases through volume limitations that don't require a physical taking. For whatever reason, in the history of the new deal, this one was set up differently. And so we're here dealing with a classical physical taking. We are not going to jeopardize the marketing, the agriculture department's marketing order regime. And by the way, it better be the department of agriculture that takes these. You said earlier it's the raisin committee or else you're going to have a lot of trouble in your government's speech cases. Where you always make the point that these committees are in fact the government. We're not, we're not saying the committee is not the government. What I was saying is that the, that the operation of the program is not for the government's benefit. It is for the producers. Correct, correct. It was not the five-on. Look, this is, I'm having trouble with the same thing. I agree so far with what the Chief Justice said. Go back to the new deal. You can in fact burn raisins, the point of which was to have fewer raisins, the result of which was to raise the price of raisins from $100 a pound or a bush old to $400. That was thought to make the farmer better off, which it did. And it made the customers worse off. Then someone had a good idea and said sort of wasteful to burn raisins. Let's take the raisins we'd otherwise burn and give them to school children. And maybe we could even sell a few. And if we do, we'll get that extra money to the farmer too. Now we have school children with raisins. We have the farmer having more money. Sounds like a pretty good program. Of course you have taken some raisins. But what I don't see is how either the farmer or the school children are any worse off. And if there are no worse off, what compensation are these farmers entitled to? Of course, free riders could become yet better off. They could charge at the higher price that the program creates $800. But after all, that isn't the issue because you have to have as a rule no free riders. And once you admit that as a rule, everyone, including perhaps these plaintiffs, are better off than none at all. Now that's a very simple argument. It's what I understand to be the economics of the Brennan Plan, the FDR, the 1949, etc. And yet we've had endless cases, complexities, opinions, and fines. And therefore I'm probably wrong with my simple argument. Of course I doubt that I'm wrong. But nonetheless, I want you to explain what's wrong with it. We agree with much of what you said, except that it is not, I just reiterated, it is not a taking of the race. You want to say it's not a take. No, it is a regulatory program classically analyzed under Penn Central because there is a reciprocity of advantage, one of the phrases this Court has frequently used among producers. This does not distinctly affect the petitioners. It applies to all producers. If petitioners are correct, since 1949, every year there has been a reserve requirement. Every producer has had a per se taking. I largely agree with what the Chief Justice said. I mean, just the way I think about this program is that this does seem a weird historical anomaly. Am I right that all the rest of these agricultural programs are done differently such that saying that this was a take-in would not affect other agricultural programs? And also, are there any other programs out there? Forget agricultural programs. But are there any other programs out there that we should be concerned about if we were to think about this as a take-in? Well, with respect to agricultural programs, I think there are eight or ten other programs that have reserve provisions in them. I think most of those are not active in the sense that there is currently reserve, just like this one is not. And if this one has outlived a usefulness, then the committee has not proposed a reserve requirement. The program is working exactly like it should. The committee, which is responsible, has decided not to impose a reserve requirement. I'm sorry, but you said that there were eight or ten other programs that you said they have... They have, like this one, provisions permitting the use of a reserve system, but like this one, they are not actively utilizing it. I think most of this has been in the last decade, I don't know precisely. And one of the things that's happened in this industry in the last ten years is it has changed greatly. You will see from the... a micus brief filed by SunMade and the Raising Bargaining Association, which I commend to your attention. They now believe that the reserve requirement should no longer be... or at least SunMade does, should no longer be instituted. But they also firmly believe that petitioners should not be permitted to be free riders on this program. And what is... And Mr. Needle, what are non-actricultural programs? Are there other regulatory programs where the government says produce something that is characterizable as property? Well, I think the most immediately relevant one, which this Court sustained, was in the Monsanto case. You were asking about records and information. That was a case in which, as a condition for marketing pesticides, the manufacturer had to submit information to EPA. Right. You know about that one. Anything else out there? I mean, tell me what the realm of regulatory programs is that we ought to be concerned about if we were to say something like the production of something, the production of stuff that somebody claims a property interest in is a taken. I'm not specifically aware of other programs, but Monsanto and the requirement to submit information to the government, for example, is widespread in our society. And what the Court basically said there was that if it was known when someone before they entered commerce and applied their application, if they knew that the material would be disclosed to the public or used by the government for approving other applications, there was no take. I guess the government can prohibit the introduction of harmful pesticides into interstate commerce. A Monsanto can prohibit the introduction of raisins. I mean, that's a dangerous raisins. I can understand imposing that condition on Monsanto, and that would not be an unconstitutional condition. Well, that is such to me it is when you impose it on raisins. Well, the Court's rationale on Monsanto was not based on the fact that it was, that the product was dangerous, although that was obviously the setting. It was the fact that the manufacturer knew when submitting the information to EPA, that it would be subject to disclosure. And therefore, its property value either eliminated or appropriated by the government as it were for use in evaluating other applications. Well, but what you've noticed from Monsanto, and looking at your brief on page 32, and you cite Monsanto, you say that producers who are dissatisfied with the reserve regulations may plant different crops. It's a pretty audacious statement. If you don't like our regulations, do something else. Well, or that's not the only option that they have. They had the option of selling the grapes for other purposes. The prime are eating wine or grape juice. These grapes, the overwhelming majority of them, the Thompson, Seedless grapes, are have a variety of uses. And that's one of the things that a grower would take into account, is what they matter all the way. We would say if you don't like regulations, you can challenge them in court to see if they comply with the Constitution. The answer, I mean, if the answer is always, you can do something else, it would seem we should never have these kinds of cases. No, but this is a substantive point I'm making, not a preclusion of review point. The substantive point is that there is market regulation, people who are growing crops in this industry know what the regulation is and if they decide, and the warranty of operated under this marketing order for 30 years before they, before they challenge all that, it seems to me that your argument, I'm sorry, just a candidate, what your argument is saying is, even if it's a taking, it's okay. It'll be okay. Everything will work out. That's what I get from the very beginning. No, our argument, our fundamental argument is that it is not a taking begin with because the grower voluntarily submits the total amount of its raisins to the handler. The handler then separates them into two quarters, one to be sold now and one to be sold later. But they both have to do with the timing and regulation of sale, which petitioners acknowledge the government can regulate the timing and manner of sale. That's exactly what happens here. There are basically two markets. One is the free market, the other is the tightly regulated market for exports, for other outlets that do not compete with the domestic market. So if you don't like, we're going to say the pledge of allegiance in public schools and we're going to make everybody stand. And if you don't like it, go to a different school. I don't understand why that's not the same analysis here. We may be taking, you know, this may be a taking of your raisins or not, but if you don't like it, grow something else. Well, Monsanto is not the only case where that was, by the way, I do not believe that no one cut back on the rationale of Monsanto. What the footnote in No-Lin said is, we do not regard the ability to build on your property, your real property, to build a house as a governmental benefit. It did not say, in fact, I think it reaffirmed the idea that there was an exchange in Monsanto, or the government was giving a benefit of clearing the public. And that was a product for use. Whereas you say that introducing raisins into interstate commerce is a government benefit, right? We think the regulatory program is a governmental benefit. No, not the regulatory. You're saying the activity which is subjected to this taking is the introduction of raisins in interstate commerce. And you say that is something that the benign government can give or withhold. It is the permission to do it, which is exactly what the court said in Monsanto. But Monsanto is not the only case. Ye said the same thing with respect to real property. That was the case involving the mobile home park. And it was claim there was a taking there because the mobile park owner was subject to rent control. And it was argued that that was just like Loretto because it was a forced physical occupation. And the court said no. The critical distinction was that the yees have voluntarily chosen to enter the rental market, to enter into a commercial transaction. And the government could then, because they have voluntarily done it, regulate the price that was being charged. Mr. McConnell was asked a number of questions about the Leonard case. But I take it that you don't think that the Leonard case has a very important bearing on this case. Because you cited one time in your brief, it's a passing reference on the issue of fungible goods. Am I correct there? We think it's a critical point. We are not, you don't think, you didn't propose, you didn't suggest to us that this case is just another version of Leonard. And therefore we should have firm based on Leonard. To the extent that Leonard was about tax, this program was not identified as a tax, partly because the raisins don't come to the government. The raisins are going to a pool that belongs to all of the producers and then is divided up among the producers. These are not things that are appropriated for the government's own use. But we think Leonard is critically instructive for the point that with respect to property like this, like the oyster shells or like raisins, what the court said is that they are fungible. Their only value is for commercial sale. This is not like the ownership of real property in Loretto, which is unique and personally identified. These raisins are valuable only for sale. And in fact, as I said, this order kicks in only when the producer has committed the raisins to sale by handling a handler. So put all the regulatory aspects of the program aside for a moment and just say this were a much simpler program. And it said the government says to the raisin industry, you know, we could tax you and say you have to deliver 2% of your net profits. We're not going to do that. We're just going to take 2% of your raisins. Would that be constitutional? Would that be a taken? That would be, I think, like Leonard. It would be an in-kind tax. I don't think there's anything that would prohibit that being done. But that's not, I mean, and we think the fact that that would be okay is instructive here as the court's discussion of Leonard suggests. But the court doesn't have to have that. But you said you don't think of this case in that way and why don't you? It's analogous in the sense that Congress may well be able to do this in a different way. The reason I said it was different is that the oysters, the raisins, excuse me, are not being used for the government's program. They do not go to school lunch programs. If the government wants raisins, it buys them. It doesn't. We don't usually allow committees of producers who are called the government to impose taxes doing. That's usually done by Congress. And this essentially is done by some committee. Right. And it's a committee elected by producers. It's important to write. So they can impose taxes, you're saying. No. What I was saying is that the government may well be able to impose something, some exactions as a tax. But this is a regulatory program adopted by producers. Again, it's important to recognize. And this goes back to the New Deal Discord. It's had numerous cases involving these marketing orders. Right. Whenever a majority of producers agree to, I have to be bound by. I mean, these people disagree. They do disagree, but the disagreement does not convert it into a taking. And if they believe the program is not operating correctly, then there are other... I'm not saying the disagreement converts it into taking. I'm just saying that it doesn't carry much water to say that this is a program adopted by producers. If 51% of the producers want to do it, there's 49 that don't want to do it. Well, I think it's a pretty good indication that the premises on which Congress enacted this statute in 1937, operated then and operated now for the benefit of producers. And it shouldn't be necessary in any one particular year in which the regulatory program is in place to calibrate whether the benefits outweigh the burdens. Central planning was thought to work very well in 1937. And Russia tried it for a long time. Well, again, if this program is not working, it can be modified. And in fact, the committee comprised of producers that's decided not to impose a reserve of whatever it is. You've made the point several times that the government sells these raisins for the benefit of the producers. Right? What if the producers, some of them think they can do a better job of selling them? They can get a better price because they're better producers, they're better marketers, they have export contacts that others don't? This is just standard regulation. What Congress has said is if you're going to sell, you have to sell, and the manner set up under this program. And the portion that's not usually what when you're talking about that type of regulation, I understand that, you know, the raisins have to be so big or you can't call them raisins and they've got to have safety inspections at all. But you've been presenting this as the reason this is a good program is because we sell the raisins and then we give some of what's left to the producers. I don't think that's a very common approach to market regulation. Well, there are two pools of raisins and how you treat or how you implement the notion that there are two different pools of raisins may vary. But where you have that, the similarities are much more fundamental. You have the free tonnage raisins which the grower is immediately paid for and the handler can immediately put on the market. But there was a judgment made when this marketing order was established and some made in the raisin association believe it was still true during these years that if you have a big surplus as there was around the turn of the century, it would make the price as plummet if those extra raisins were put on the open market because the demand for raisins is inelastic. So what this marketing order does is it estimates what word operates, estimates what the free tonnage requirement will be and that is completely open to the market. The reserve raisins, if you, they're essentially valueless because you don't need them to satisfy the existing market, you take them off the market to prop up the prices of the free tonnage raisins and then the committee will sell them when they will not undermine or in a manner that will not undermine the free tonnage raisins. Suppose this sort of program were carried out with respect to real property, would you provide the same answer, suppose that property owners owners of real property in a particular area, think that the value of their property would be increased if they all surrender to certain amount of that property to the government for the purpose of producing a, creating a park or for some other reason. And so they get the municipality to, to set up this program and one of them objects to surrendering this part of that person of, of his or her land. Would, would that not be a taking? I think real property would be fundamentally different. Well, why would it be fun? I thought you said you're not arguing that there's a difference between real property and personal property. We're not saying there's a categorical difference, but I think, I think the Lucas decision is very instructive there that when, when the court was talking about the ability to regulate real property, it said that there's a big difference between real property and personal property, at least personal property being used for commercial purposes, which might even be rendered valueless by virtue of governmental regulation. So we should need their, let's sketch the limitations on a taking scale. Six years, I think it would be. Has there been any reserves created in the last six years? I think the last one was 2009, 2010. I wanted to correct one fact. Explain to me why, why the market for raisins is inelastic. You mean people won't buy more raisins if they're cheaper? That's basically correct. It's just a quality of, it's just a quality of raisins. And there's a limited set of outlets. Raisins now are primarily used as food ingredients and raising brand and things like that. And the price doesn't affect demand. And therefore, if you put a great surplus on the domestic market, the price is well cratered. And so this has a very sensible approach. Mr. Neeter, you don't have to convince us that this is a sensible program for you to prevail, do you? No, we do not. We could think that this is a ridiculous program. Isn't that right? I'm sorry. We could think that this is a ridiculous program, but it is one that has been around since 1949. And Petitioner's argument again means that every grower since 1949 has had a per se take-ins. I mean, I don't think it does. Help your case that it's ridiculous, though. You act all of it. It is not, let me be clear, a ridiculous program. But this is a serious point, actually, because the ridiculousness or sensableness of a program is really not for us to decide. Yes, I agree with that completely. I mean, that is our, this is a regulatory program and should be thought of under this Court's regulatory first. Mr. Neeter, you asked this before, but your answer wasn't clear. Markley-Mortez of this sort that have a reserve pool. You said there were eight or ten of them. Have any others been operative as this one has been? That's just starting in 1949. And how many days? I have been operative in the past. Most of them are not operative, operative in the sense that the reserve, this is my understanding that the reserve provision has been triggered. Those is the government selling the reserve. I think it's true of maybe several others. I'm not sure. Some of them have to do with the handler difference between handler and producer. I want to correct, I'll go ahead. I want to correct a factual error on the computation. So there was suggestion in the one year there was $810, was the field price. And because of the mathematical calculations, the claim was that the petitions would have been better off without the reserve. That's not correct. The mistake there is the assumption that all the raisins would have been sold at the field price if they were all put on the market. And that's just inconsistent with the premise of the order. That the only reason that there is a high field price for the free tonnage raisins is that the other ones are taken off the market. So they would not have been recovered in that way. How many of these programs are there of marketing orders? I think there are scores of them. Actually, I mean, I'm trying to put the 8 to 10 in relation to how many. I don't know the total number, but we can follow that up with a supplemental letter. I think there are scores of them. But this is not fundamentally different from the others. And again, the government is not acquiring these raisins for itself. The government doesn't actually keep them in its possession. It just tells the handler to keep them and sell them later rather than selling them now. And that is not an appropriation of private property. Thank you, Council. Mr. McConnell, you have five minutes remaining. Thank you, Mr. Chief Justice. So several things have been cleared up. The government now does concede that the government takes legal title to the raisins. The government does have to or are in our case. We're just seeing all the time. To the extent that we've issued taking formal titles as meaningful with respect to actual control or actual benefit, we trustees take title and but it's not for their benefits for the benefit of their beneficiary. That's true, Justice Sotomayor, but the government is not a trustee here. And the... Oh, but in a form, yes. It's still right to sell the reserve raisins at the best price it can get given the limitations on the free market. It sells for the best price and then it uses the proceeds for its own regulatory purpose. You have only four minutes in rebellion. You had some other points. Just as to the factual point, it is not... Our calculations are not based upon selling all of the raisins at the field price. Our calculations are based upon being able to sell all the raisins at the price that the secretary has said would be the price in an unregulated market, which is $747 per ton. And that is, it is certainly not true that these reserve raisins are valueless. They are an extremely valuable commodity and in most of the years, the producers of the raisins receive absolutely nothing for them. The important point here, though, is that it is not any less of a taking, even if there is a benefit. I have no doubt, for example, that in Loretto, that the value of the apartment went up because there was a cable, because it became cable ready for its tenants. That did not make it any less of a taking, as this is a per se taking, and any benefits only go to whether there might be some kind of implicit, in kind, a compensation as a result of the benefit. And if this were an imminent domain proceeding, I think that that might well be relevant. This is, in fact, only an administrative enforcement action in which the question is whether the Department of Agriculture was entitled under the Constitution to demand either the raisins or their monetary equivalent without any payment of compensation. That lasts. Why isn't it for them to make that argument? Because you know, you're better off, et cetera. If you would look at the, is it a way to do that? I mean, what's the, what's the, no, it's the regulation. I'm, I'm sorry, if you look at 7 CFR 989.166C, you will see that that is the provision for what happens when the handler does not turn over reserve raisins to the Department of Agriculture. It is, it has very specific provisions for what happens, and there is no provision in that for implicit and kind compensation. But just, can they argue that, the fact that all the raisin producers are better off because of this program, including you, but no free riders. That's what's the compensation. Can they at least argue that, or if they conceded that? Under this regulation, I do not think it is open to the Department of Agriculture to argue that. I think that that would be a logical argument if this were an imminent domain proceeding, and we were simply trying to figure out what the proper value of the raisins is. Reserving, of course, the point that we believe that this program does not benefit the producer. We believe that the, we believe that this program actually makes the producers demonstrably worse off. The only people who benefit from this program are the recipients of the subsidy, of the export subsidies. The export is, that's right. Mr. Montgomery, why take you back to the very first thing that you said in this argument? Because you said, typically, the handler doesn't take the product, and the handler doesn't pay for the product. And you would think that the horns here would only have a takings claim, assuming that they do have a takings claim for the raisins that they produced, and not for the raisins that other people produced. But you said that that's not correct in this case? It is not, because they pay the, they, a check went out from the Raisin Marketing Association to the producers for every raisin, not just the free tonnage raisins, but for the reserve tonnage raisins as well. So the horns are actually the only people with a financial interest in the raisins in this case. That is unusual. Mr. McConaughey, this is probably neither here nor there, but what is the impact of the drought been on the raisin producers? Do you know? It is not good. It's very carefully guarded respite. And I wonder, I wonder if I'll be able to take a shower when I go on. Thank you, counsel. The case is submitted