We'll hear argument first this morning in case 15, 3, 7, 5, Supap Kurt sang versus John Wiley and sons. Mr. Rosencrantz? Thank you, Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the Court. When Congress modified the American rule in the Copyright Act, it was not just trying to punish those who took unreasonable positions. It wanted to encourage parties to advance important principles even where the other side's arguments are good, indeed I would say especially where the other side's arguments are good. When a defendant is trying to decide whether to fight for a principle, the availability of attorney's fees can make all the difference in that decision, and in turn can make all the difference in whether the public's rights are vindicated. The second circuit standard flouts the plain language of the statute undermines Congress's goal and is inconsistent with this Court's opinion in poverty. It does nothing to encourage a defendant who has a good defense but is facing off against a powerful adversary armed with a reasonable position. That encouragement has not happened once in the last 15 years. That's not once. In 187 cases decided under the Second Circuit's Matthew Bender rubric, and will never happen anywhere outside the Second Circuit. If the Court's saying had lost this case, if he had lost this case, should he have been awarded to Wiley, given the significance of this decision, it's an important decision. It needs both sides to be aired before the Court. So, suppose he had lost, and Wiley won, would Wiley be entitled to attorney's fees? Why would we have an argument, Your Honor, certainly on one of the factors that we have suggested, which is it would say we won an important case. It didn't win against the Court. It would have had more than that. It would have had circuit precedent. It could have been found. Willfully infringing, correct? And why would it be? I would say yes to that question, wouldn't you? I'm sorry. Our client would have been, it was already found to a willfully infringing. So, our client had a lot already weighing against him, but just to get back to finish the answer to Justice Ginsburg's question, but there would have been other factors. The Court would have evaluated what the incentives for both sides were. So, Wiley would have had an enormous economic incentive to advance its position. Court saying would have had much less of an incentive to do anything other than to cave
. Why? It was a lucrative business he was engaged in. Your Honor, he was a student who had this side business who was making just a few dollars per book. I mean, it was a large volume, but the problem 100,000. Several hundred thousand dollars in revenues, Your Honor, but not in profit. And as to Wiley, as to the books of Wiley that he sold, it was $37,000, Your Honor, for which he was hit with a $600,000 judgment, which also would have been considered by the district court. It would have thought, it would have asked itself, is this fair? But the problem with the Second Circuit's position is that it free judges in every case there is going to be substantial weight on the reasonableness. Kagan-Mister Rosenkantz, just to continue on with what Justice Ginsburg was asking you, as an ex-post matter, you have a great David versus Goliath story to tell. But as an ex-anti-matter, I wonder if the rule that you suggest is not going to harm the Court's ends of the world. And, you know, you might take in these couple of things into account that the Court's ends of the world will probably think that they are spending less on their lawyers than the John Wiley's of the world, and that they're also more risk-averse because they have less money. So, you know, given those two factors, doesn't your rule, actually, as an ex-anti-matter, cut against the Court's ends of the rule? You're under the answer is no, and for this reason. The Court's sayings of the world when they are facing off against the John Wiley, the first question on their minds before they ever think about attorneys' fees being awarded against them is, how am I going to pay for this? And critical answer to that question will be in many circumstances there's the availability of attorneys' fees. Kagan-Mister Rosenkantz, just to say, that's only one side of the question. I mean, what you're doing is you're upping the stakes generally so that the Court's end is going to know, well, it's true I might be able to get my fees back, but at the same time, I run the risk of having to pay John Wiley's fees, and John Wiley, as I said, is probably going to be paying its lawyers more than I'm going to be paying mine, and I'm very risk-sensitive as a Court's end type. So, that's a huge deal for me to increase my stakes that much. You're on a understood. That will be part of the calculus. Now, in the ninth circuit where the test that we are suggesting predominates, and in every circuit that doesn't accept the second circuit's position, which is to say every other circuit, there is not a derth of copyright litigation. People in a Court saying's position are fighting ahead, and why is that? It's because district courts have been entrusted with making reasonable judgments and asking the question. If a defendant is in exactly this position in the next case, what are the incentives that will appropriately incentivize both the plaintiff to push on and the defendant? I thought you told us that there haven't been any awards under the, maybe I misunderstood, the second circuit test in 15 years, or what was the point you were making beginning 187 cases, 15 years? 178 cases, Your Honor, that were decided under the second circuit's Matthew Bender standard. Not once did any defendant that is ever prevail in receiving attorney's fees except where the plaintiff has been, has engaged in unreasonable, unreasonable. So, but I thought your point now is that the defendants in copyright cases still show up. No, Your Honor, I'm talking about the rest of the world. I'm talking about the ninth circuit. So, in the ninth circuit, plaintiff show up, starving artists show up, and starving artists defend
. And they don't in the second circuit? Well, the truth is there are very few starving artists in any copyright litigation. So, yes, they may show up, but they won't be able to pay for their own lawyer. And so, suggested one of the solutions to that problem is for the district court to take into account the relative financial resources of the parties. Is that correct? Yes, Your Honor, as one of the factors. So, what the district court should do in every case, in addition to all of the footnote 19 factors, is to ask itself, if a party in the same position reads the precedence, or their lawyers read the precedence, what lessons will they clean from them? And one of the things a district court should be analyzing in every case looking backwards is what would have been the right economic incentives for this plaintiff and this defendant? Have they ever said that in that? Have we ever said that the availability of attorney's fees is dependent on the financial resources of the party? Your Honor, it's certainly, it has long been a part of the standard that courts have consistently applied in attorney's fees cases. This court said in Fogarty, you've got to evaluate the incentives. And the incentives run both ways. And John Wiley did not need attorney's fees in order to proceed and was not worried about attorney's fees in order to protect its interests in a $1.8 billion a year business for which, on this particular issue, it's stood to gain hundreds of millions of dollars. It wasn't worried about whether it would have to pay Sam Israel's $125,000 in fees. A court saying, on the other hand, would have been worried about that under any standard. And in a standard where he stands to gain attorney's fees for defending, that would have been an important incentive to encourage him to soldier on. It wasn't as it does sound like as Justice Kagan put it, the general rule is if David bases Goliath and David wins, David gets fees no matter how reasonable Goliath's position was. That's what it seems to come down to. Sotomayor. Your Honor, it doesn't. On that factor of, I mean, there are easily six factors a court should be considering. On that factor, a David is better positioned than a Goliath to make the argument that he should get fees. But there's a lot more to it. There's what else does the defendant stand to gain? What does the plaintiff stand to gain? What were the motivations of the parties? One of the factors that the district court said was completely irrelevant was, what was the significance of the win to the public? So all of the, so I'm one thing that concerns me about a test like that, Mr. Rosen Kranz, is it's very hard for people to make judgments ex-antig and to figure out what their chances are. It's very hard to predict. And if you're concerned about the court's ends of the world, the David's in these kinds of suits, what you might want is a pretty clear, safe harbor. In other words, if I'm taking a reasonable position, I'm not going to be stuck with the other side's fees, which are likely to dwarf my own
. And that's something that somebody can predict, as opposed to this 22-factor test, which it's like, I just don't know how this is going to come out. And I might well be stuck with John Wiley's fees, depending on what judge I draw on and all number of other things that I don't have any control over. S. Wiley, you're right. So what the Congress did was to select a standard based upon the total of the stability of the circumstances. It affirmatively rejected the standard that sat there in the patent act and in the Lanham act that was based on exactly the clear line that you described your honor exceptional circumstances. To this day, Wiley has not explained how its test is any different from the one that Congress adopted. It's exactly what is it? What is it but what is it? I suppose I start this thinking, this big judges do have a job. And part of that job, they do things that we would do worse, not better. And one of the things that they know is the case in front of them and what we said in our case was it's up to them as long as they act reasonably. So you started with a factor which I guess they could have taken into account. Nothing in our law prohibits it. In fact, it encourages it. So what's the problem? What is it? Are you saying we should in fact change what we said in Fogarty? In my own mind, I don't know how to do it. No, you're on the right. We don't want to leave that. Okay. So you want a case-specific correction of what you believe is a failure to apply, to realize what Fogarty meant is not the idea? Yes, Your Honor. So let me be more precise. I've already said one of the things that is wrong with the MacUbender's standard that it is a textual. The second thing directly to the question on Fogarty is that Fogarty says, quote, defendants who seek to advance maritalist, corporate defenses should be encouraged to litigate them. There is nothing in MacUbender that encourages a defendant to litigate. No, but you want us to case-specific or you want us to say something. One whole, one result would be the second circuit seems not to have taken account of what we said, which is that all considerations, all considerations that are consistent with the purposes of the Copyright Act can be relevant
. It depends on the case. Period. Absolutely, Your Honor. Although I would add a little bit more. I would say- You added this other thing, which I don't know how to do. The other thing is whether you really advance the law. I mean, maybe at the time, Marbury versus Madison was viewed by many people as being just about an appointment, and it didn't really advance the law. Your Honor. Maybe you thought it did. I don't know. How do we know which advances the law? Your Honor, district courts know what cases are advancing the law and what cases- Sotomayor. I think that Justice Breyer is getting to something. Put on a hat that doesn't want to win outright. Okay. Put on a hat where we're trying to announce a rule. And I'm sympathetic to your argument that the second circuit rule obviously stacks everything in favor of a winning plaintiff, published, winning copyright holder, because 80 percent are now winning, if not more, in the second circuit, it's almost 89 percent. It means when you're talking about the reasonableness of a winning party's position, in most cases, the copyright holder has a reasonable position. And the defendant by losing tends to have an unreasonable position. I looked at what happened after Fogarty, and the after Fogarty's being infanticie, that's where the ninth circuit test began. And the court they are said, there's different incentives for plaintiffs and defendants. You can't make the reasonableness of the position, the centerpiece for prevailing defendants, or otherwise they're never going to get fees or hardly ever. So going back to Justice Breyer's question, how do we articulate what the second circuit is doing wrong without necessarily endorsing all of the factors of the ninth circuit? Sotomayor, the simple answer is what the second circuit did was to pick one factor out of a jumble of possible factors and say, this will be the one that gets substantial weight. And what the district courts do with that is then hold up that one factor and ask, is there anything that outweighs that factor, when in the context of a particular case, that might not be the most important factor. But I see the court by the way
. The test would be it's okay to have it one among others, but not a presumption that says, that's always going to entitle you to defend against an award or to win an award. And what Matthew Bender does is essentially to announce a presumption. But I see the court wrestling with how to articulate a test. I can articulate the test in four sentences in a way that district courts can administer. So our rule is that a district court should consider the totality of the circumstances including all of the Fogarty factors. And ask itself, would a fee award here advance the purposes of the Copyright Act? Is this the sort of case in which, if the same scenario were to present itself again, the availability of fees would create the right litigation incentives, that is, for both parties, with the right result for the public. The district court should consider each of the Fogarty factors and do it through the lands of the purposes of the Copyright Act. It should also consider the significance and nature of the win and the litigation incentives on both sides of the view, including any disparity in resources. That is, if this court were to say those four sentences, district courts would have a lot of guidance. And if this court were to say Fogarty 2 actually does it right, it didn't just consider litigation incentives on one side. It considered the litigation incentives for the plaintiff. But it seems to me that you, a party can advance the law and a case can advance the law by insisting on principle, consistent application of settled principles. That's an advance in the law. I can see the excitement about granting fees if there's some, from breakthrough, something we've never thought about. On the other hand, there's something that's commendable about applying the law consistently, routinely in regular cases. That advances the law. Of course it does. And in the right case that can support a ease award, for example, the only way to define fair use is case by case, accretively, where a common law develops. Someone who advances a fair use defense and wins ought to be at least within range of a copyright. The back to your test now, which you say will make it something district court can understand and readily apply. So take my question. Forks and newses and widely-wins, apply your four-setting test and tell me when the answer will depend on a district court specific balancing, but I'll do the balance that I would do that I would argue to the district court. I would say, well, first, widely did win something really big here, although it wasn't against huge headwinds, the precedent was in its favor. Good for widely, it gets credit for that
. But widely had every incentive to protect hundreds of millions of dollars. It didn't need attorneys fees in order to incentivize it. Kurtzeng also did something important. It stood up, he stood up, he had a reasonable position. That counts. It's not dispositive, but it counts. And what good would it have, would it have mutual litigants, would it do for mutual litigants to hit this poor guy who was a student, would it turn ease fees, what he's already got a $600,000 judgment against him? That would be my app, because see I could see a district court adopting it. I could see a district court going the other way. But a common law will emerge as it has in the ninth circuit. Impicunious defendants are not shying away from fighting a big copyright goliaths if they can afford the lawsuit that is to pay their own attorneys fees. There's rampant copyright litigation in the ninth circuit and in the other circuits that don't start with a presumption against attorney's fees if the other side was reasonable. Can I ask Mr. Rosengrenz? One of the things that confused me about this case and about actually both sides are arguments. I don't really understand why it is that the fees are awarded in such a high percentage of the cases, both in the second circuit and elsewhere. I mean, the second circuit says that it's the first among equal factors is the reason there's a reasonable mess. But it awards fees in more way more than half the cases. Is it that so many of the cases are utterly frivolous? Well, so you are to the answer as two parts. There is a different test for defendants than for plaintiffs, not withstanding what you read and Matthew Bender. So before you talk to me about the way this might or might not be pro plaintiff or pro defendants, just why are they also high? Well, the numbers are so high for plaintiffs because plaintiffs are generally getting copyright fees even if the other side was perfectly reasonable because there's a blameworthiness element to it. So this, you know, this so and so infringer should be smacked with the attorney's fees. And by the way, there's often willfulness as there was in this case because a legal defense is no defense. On the defendant's side, in the second circuit is certainly not more than half. It's a round half. And that's only where the other side has behaved unreasonably, either in its litigation position, that is the validity of its claim or in its litigation position's sort of aggressive tactics
. Those are the only circumstances in 178 cases in which defendants have ever had copyright fees awarded in their favor. And this is something that we have yet to hear. Well, you know, I have no idea why. I could speculate one problem is that a lot of college students think they should listen to all the music they want and they don't pay any copyright. That would be outrageous. Right? I read that in the papers in other places as a problem. So maybe from time to time the copyright owners feel that, you know, my employees have to pay for gasoline at Exxon. Why should Exxon's employees take all my works for free? Sure you are. And that's why. So we have no idea why, at least from these briefs, I have no idea why the copyright numbers come out the way they do on fees. Therefore, I'm thinking quite honestly, it's going to vary from case to case. I understand that the pellet lawyers love to create standards. I do not have that love at this moment. I understand the lack of love. If that's what the, what is motivating the Court, it should reject Matthew Bender. That might be. You could say we go back and say, have they taken what used to be an oil factory's test and have they, in fact, said, and then we could all go home. We say that we say what they've done here is they've said, we're never going to. We're hardly ever going to take a favorable account of having clarified the law. And in your view, we should say as well, don't say never, don't lay down a standard. There are too many different kinds of cases, beware of trying to, is that what you are? Yes. And I would also encourage the Court to say, when a, when a district court is evaluating each factor, it should be thinking to itself, what's the purpose? Now, you have added a couple of standards. Your first two sentences were fine. They said roughly what we've been talking about
. And then you had two later sentences, which I began to think, hey, that's going to be a little tough to apply. Your Honor, my later sentences, you are right, were two sentences. One is, think of the Fogridi factors in footnote 9 and do it through the lens of the purposes of the copyright act. And the second is, by the way, Fogridi was about more than footnote 19. It was about incentivizing each side correctly. Don't forget about that. So consider the incentives on both sides. The problem with that is that different judges are going to have very different views about what will further the purposes of the copyright act. Don't you think both the second circuit and the ninth circuit? I'm sorry, the seventh circuit. Think that their rules are the rules that best further the purposes of the copyright act. Yes, Your Honor. And that's why both of them are wrong. I would love the Court to adopt the seventh circuit standard, but it too free, free judges, in every case, it says, here's what will further the purposes of the copyright. And the footnote does not say further the purposes of the act. What the footnote says is, Judge, when you award these fees, be certain that you are faithful to the purposes of the act. And that's very different. It means don't do something that's going to undermine the act. As opposed to sitting there and figuring out whether the basic purpose of the act is to what extent to encourage authors at the expense of the readers or the expense of those people who do not want to undergo huge transaction costs getting a hold of dead authors. All right. So we have several different conflicting purposes. You want to bring them in when you say further, and the Court did not bring them in, because it said, are faithful to, you don't have to answer. No, Your Honor. My answer is very short. Yes
. I agree. I accept what I think is a friendly amendment to my description, Ogerty. Thank you, Your Honor. Thank you, counsel. Thank you. Mr. Smith? Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the Court, this is a case I submit where the lower courts did everything right. As courts have been doing in copyright cases for more than a century, the district court focused first on the question of whether or not the losing party here Wiley had taken an unreasonable litigation position on the law or on the facts and concluded that it obviously had not. And then it looked at all the other potentially relevant factors, including all of the factors that had been suggested by Court saying it's counsel, and concluded that- Except there is, Mr. Smith, I'm troubled by what's happening in the Second Circuit. I've actually, with the help of the Library, looked at cases in the Second and the Ninth Circuit for the last three years. And this is what I'm coming out with. In the Ninth Circuit, prevailing defendants have received these 20 times and lost 17 times, about 50 percent. In the Second Circuit, prevailing defendants have received these three times and lost 16 times. It's a huge difference. If I look at what's happening with prevailing plaintiffs, in the Second Circuit, prevailing plaintiffs awarded these 23 times and prevailing plaintiffs denied these seven. In the Ninth, prevailing plaintiffs got it 46 times and denied these twice. Prevailing plaintiffs are winning everywhere in extraordinary numbers, and in both circuits prevailing defendants are not winning hardly at all at best 50 percent in the Ninth Circuit. So does it say something that somehow prevailing defend that this presumption that the Second Circuit is giving is unfair to defendants and to the purposes of a copyright law? No, Your Honor. First of all, I would note that Mr. Kurtzeng's own attorneys had reported that if a more complete study of the Second Circuit record says that defendants are winning them 50 percent of the time. Sorry. 5-0? Yes, Your Honor
. That's in their reply brief. But that was a study from 2000, correct? No, no, no. They did their own study and they reported that in their reply brief and said they would not have the data if you want. The 80 percent figure that they report for plaintiffs in the Second Circuit includes, by the way, a great number of default judgments where fees are both very small and not as in this area. I know you're right. So, you know, these statistics can be thrown around there. It is not as if defendants in general are not succeeding in getting attorney's fees when they're appropriate. But is there a problem in having one factor outweigh all others? It's much harder to start with a resumption up here and all the other factors have to tie against that one to overcome it. But why don't we just have the Fogarty factors which are, it's one among many? Your Honor, two responses. First of all, when people, when judges, are given discretion to award fees, looking at whether the losing party had a substantial case or not, is there something that, instinctively, you arrive at. That's the standard you were enunciated and obtained for the patent. It's the standard that you were enunciated in Martin for the removal statute. Of course, that's what you give a lot of primacy to in deciding whether in your discretion as judges you're going to shift fees from alter the American rule or not. That's just natural. It's what courts have been doing under the Copyright Act since 1909. That is the law that was reported to Congress when they re-enacted this provision in 1976 in the Brown study and the Register report. Congress understood that what the way the rule works is that fees are being shifted when one side of the other has an unreasonable litigation. But since most plaintiffs are not going to sue unless their position is arguably reasonably present, shouldn't we be looking at how reasonable the defendant's position was? You do when they when they play the plaintiff. But it's a defendant wins. When the defendant wins, if you have a rule that says we're going to shift fees against reasonable plaintiffs, then you're going to have the wrong incentives. When you have a case where both sides have a reasonable position, what you're trying to do in that case under Fogarty is incentivize both parties to keep litigating so that the law can be clarified. This is a classic example here. This is a case that was a complete coin flip because the law was totally indeterminate. Nobody knew whether the first sale doctor to apply it here or didn't apply here. There was no law in the second circuit when the case was filed. By the time the case gets to this court, this court has already ruled four to four that the on the issue. So nobody was it was a coin flip. And in that situation, the last thing you want to do to the parties if you're trying to get them to keep litigating so that the issue gets clarified is telling, oh, by the way, we're going to raise the stakes. Whoever wins is going to get fees and whoever loses is going to have to pay double. That's just not the way risk-averse profit maximizing participants in litigation behave. If you want to, you suppress litigation by imposing the British rule presumptively in this kind of case because people simply aren't going to keep fighting. They're going to find a way to get out of the case. As you understand the petitioner's position, do they take the argument you've just made about the necessity for continuing the litigation and then add a David and Goliath factor to it? Is that your understanding of their position or my mind? Sotomayor's understanding of their position and it is a little hard to nail down your honor. It seems to vary at times. From pages 41 of the merits brief, the blue brief, and what they say there is, if the result of the litigation is to clarify the law, then whichever party has the good fortune of being the winner, wins the coin flip, gets fees. That's what they say generally is happening. The question is, if you're not getting a good margin from that, is you're getting a good margin from that, Lisa, you say, just don't say never. And indeed the Second Circuit did say never. It said a court should not award attorney's fees, where the case is novel or closed because such a litigation clarifies the boundaries of copyright law. So you did not say never, Your Honor, the rule in the Second Circuit is that other factors can overrule that and indeed the Court has, the Second Circuit has so said. They have so many of this here. And they were quoting, it says, as this Court is reasonably explained, am I in the right place? I'm in page 18A, 19A of the petition. Maybe I'm reading the wrong opinion that's been known. And what they do is they quote, it says, as this Court recently explained, and it seems to me they underline the word not, so I may mount a credit properly. I don't know. But you are not. Anyway, your position is it shouldn't be never. And that is the law
. There was no law in the second circuit when the case was filed. By the time the case gets to this court, this court has already ruled four to four that the on the issue. So nobody was it was a coin flip. And in that situation, the last thing you want to do to the parties if you're trying to get them to keep litigating so that the issue gets clarified is telling, oh, by the way, we're going to raise the stakes. Whoever wins is going to get fees and whoever loses is going to have to pay double. That's just not the way risk-averse profit maximizing participants in litigation behave. If you want to, you suppress litigation by imposing the British rule presumptively in this kind of case because people simply aren't going to keep fighting. They're going to find a way to get out of the case. As you understand the petitioner's position, do they take the argument you've just made about the necessity for continuing the litigation and then add a David and Goliath factor to it? Is that your understanding of their position or my mind? Sotomayor's understanding of their position and it is a little hard to nail down your honor. It seems to vary at times. From pages 41 of the merits brief, the blue brief, and what they say there is, if the result of the litigation is to clarify the law, then whichever party has the good fortune of being the winner, wins the coin flip, gets fees. That's what they say generally is happening. The question is, if you're not getting a good margin from that, is you're getting a good margin from that, Lisa, you say, just don't say never. And indeed the Second Circuit did say never. It said a court should not award attorney's fees, where the case is novel or closed because such a litigation clarifies the boundaries of copyright law. So you did not say never, Your Honor, the rule in the Second Circuit is that other factors can overrule that and indeed the Court has, the Second Circuit has so said. They have so many of this here. And they were quoting, it says, as this Court is reasonably explained, am I in the right place? I'm in page 18A, 19A of the petition. Maybe I'm reading the wrong opinion that's been known. And what they do is they quote, it says, as this Court recently explained, and it seems to me they underline the word not, so I may mount a credit properly. I don't know. But you are not. Anyway, your position is it shouldn't be never. And that is the law. That is the law on the Second Circuit, the Viva video case, the Salusky case, both fired in the Court. Mr. Smith, when you have a system which the Second Circuit does, of saying, look, this is the first among equal factors and you need something, you know, pretty exceptional to outweigh this factor. If I'm a district judge and I'm thinking, you know, who likes to be overruled by the Second Circuit, it does seem as though it sends a pretty strong signal to district courts that this is the key factor and that they are not, you know, probably not in their lifetimes going to see a case in which that factor is outweighed. The factor that cannot weigh it and has outweighed is litigation misconduct. So you end up in the Second Circuit with a rule very much like the rule that this Court enunciated for patent law, which is if the case is unreasonable on either side or if there's been something that has magnified the cost of litigation through litigation abuse, those are situations in which courts appropriately and their discretion should award fees. But if we have two reasonable parties litigating appropriately and they simply don't know who's going to win because the law is unclear, we don't want to raise the stakes in that situation because those are the people you want to keep fighting and this case is a perfect illustration that the point where this case is going to go to this Court, you've already divided four to four. Nobody knows where Justice Kagan's going to come out on the issue. The first Court saying has to decide whether to file that cert petition. He knows at that point that he's going to get free representation, but if you had petitioner's rule, in effect, he would also be, know that he had a 50 percent chance of losing in this Court and having to pay all of John Wiley's attorney fees. Sotomayor, you mentioned that he's getting free representation. Do you, you mentioned the fact that he was represented by pro bono counsel? Is that a factor that the Court should take into consideration? I think it can affect the other factors that are relevant under Fogarty in particular the recent compensation. You don't need to compensate Mr. Kurtzain for a representation that he didn't pay for. It seems to me that's quite an intrusion into the relationship between the party and counsel. I mean, do you look at it and say, oh, well, you have discovery about whether what the relationship was between him and his counsel? I think it's a counsel giving a discount in fees and all that. I'm not sure that should be a pertinent consideration. Perhaps not. I mean, it didn't have any major impact on the outcome here, but it certainly was something that the district court mentioned, and in fact, the Second Circuit kind of disagreed with them on that in a footnote in their opinion. But the main thing is that you don't want to have a rule that says, if you file that cert petition, Mr. Kurtz saying, you're going to be 50 percent chance you're going to have a big bill at the end of it. And even from the point of view of John Wiley, sure, it's a big company, and it's a repeat player and everything, but look where they were, once Mr. Kurtz saying, file that cert petition, if petitioners rule is in place, they know they have a 50 percent chance of losing in the Supreme Court and having to pay not only all their lawyers fees, but all of Mr. Kurtzain
. That is the law on the Second Circuit, the Viva video case, the Salusky case, both fired in the Court. Mr. Smith, when you have a system which the Second Circuit does, of saying, look, this is the first among equal factors and you need something, you know, pretty exceptional to outweigh this factor. If I'm a district judge and I'm thinking, you know, who likes to be overruled by the Second Circuit, it does seem as though it sends a pretty strong signal to district courts that this is the key factor and that they are not, you know, probably not in their lifetimes going to see a case in which that factor is outweighed. The factor that cannot weigh it and has outweighed is litigation misconduct. So you end up in the Second Circuit with a rule very much like the rule that this Court enunciated for patent law, which is if the case is unreasonable on either side or if there's been something that has magnified the cost of litigation through litigation abuse, those are situations in which courts appropriately and their discretion should award fees. But if we have two reasonable parties litigating appropriately and they simply don't know who's going to win because the law is unclear, we don't want to raise the stakes in that situation because those are the people you want to keep fighting and this case is a perfect illustration that the point where this case is going to go to this Court, you've already divided four to four. Nobody knows where Justice Kagan's going to come out on the issue. The first Court saying has to decide whether to file that cert petition. He knows at that point that he's going to get free representation, but if you had petitioner's rule, in effect, he would also be, know that he had a 50 percent chance of losing in this Court and having to pay all of John Wiley's attorney fees. Sotomayor, you mentioned that he's getting free representation. Do you, you mentioned the fact that he was represented by pro bono counsel? Is that a factor that the Court should take into consideration? I think it can affect the other factors that are relevant under Fogarty in particular the recent compensation. You don't need to compensate Mr. Kurtzain for a representation that he didn't pay for. It seems to me that's quite an intrusion into the relationship between the party and counsel. I mean, do you look at it and say, oh, well, you have discovery about whether what the relationship was between him and his counsel? I think it's a counsel giving a discount in fees and all that. I'm not sure that should be a pertinent consideration. Perhaps not. I mean, it didn't have any major impact on the outcome here, but it certainly was something that the district court mentioned, and in fact, the Second Circuit kind of disagreed with them on that in a footnote in their opinion. But the main thing is that you don't want to have a rule that says, if you file that cert petition, Mr. Kurtz saying, you're going to be 50 percent chance you're going to have a big bill at the end of it. And even from the point of view of John Wiley, sure, it's a big company, and it's a repeat player and everything, but look where they were, once Mr. Kurtz saying, file that cert petition, if petitioners rule is in place, they know they have a 50 percent chance of losing in the Supreme Court and having to pay not only all their lawyers fees, but all of Mr. Kurtzain. I mean, are you seriously suggesting it's a tough call for them whether to oppose the cert petition or not? Well, maybe not, but I think it's important to look at the economic situation. They had a $600,000 judgment and they would have known under his rule they had a 50 percent chance of winning in the annual revenues. What are the annual revenues? What are the annual revenues? Mr. Rosengrasse said $1.8 billion, maybe that's correct. I don't know, actually, you're on it. But it is certainly a substantial publishing outfit, and it's a repeat player and had incentives to litigate this case. But I don't think you can do these things sort of after the fact on each party's particular incentives. You need a rule that says to people, here's how we're going to decide these things, so you have predictability. So people can tell whether or not this is likely to be for you. The problem with your situation is that you're looking at incentives. If I'm wily, I'm looking at this and saying, there's a 90 percent chance, 80 to 90 percent chance I'm going to get fees. Because woeful infringers, and that's the judgment that was being defended below, almost always the winning plaintiff gets fees. If I'm a defendant, I'm Kurt Sanger. I know that the probability is taking Mr. Rosengrasse numbers are that maybe 50 percent prevailing defendants get fees. Without pro bono counsel, do you think he would have continued? I assume he probably would have gone into debt for it. I don't know the answer, but the incentives are very, very different for a defendant who's being asked to go on with the litigation because the likelihood of them getting fees is so much smaller. I think there was never any significant likelihood of anybody getting fees under a proper application of the Second Circuit's rule here, because obviously both sides had objectively reasonable positions. And I just don't think that that is something that would have happened in the past. You've got a willfulness found below. How do you get a willfulness found in a situation where you know there's a circuit where there's a chance of a split court, court of four? Well, the conduct was intentional, but the law was 50-50. There was a complete coin flip. And so it seems to me that while he says we don't want to predetermine discretion here, the reality is you have to have some structure to the decision making so people can predict what the outcome is going to be and be incentivized
. I mean, are you seriously suggesting it's a tough call for them whether to oppose the cert petition or not? Well, maybe not, but I think it's important to look at the economic situation. They had a $600,000 judgment and they would have known under his rule they had a 50 percent chance of winning in the annual revenues. What are the annual revenues? What are the annual revenues? Mr. Rosengrasse said $1.8 billion, maybe that's correct. I don't know, actually, you're on it. But it is certainly a substantial publishing outfit, and it's a repeat player and had incentives to litigate this case. But I don't think you can do these things sort of after the fact on each party's particular incentives. You need a rule that says to people, here's how we're going to decide these things, so you have predictability. So people can tell whether or not this is likely to be for you. The problem with your situation is that you're looking at incentives. If I'm wily, I'm looking at this and saying, there's a 90 percent chance, 80 to 90 percent chance I'm going to get fees. Because woeful infringers, and that's the judgment that was being defended below, almost always the winning plaintiff gets fees. If I'm a defendant, I'm Kurt Sanger. I know that the probability is taking Mr. Rosengrasse numbers are that maybe 50 percent prevailing defendants get fees. Without pro bono counsel, do you think he would have continued? I assume he probably would have gone into debt for it. I don't know the answer, but the incentives are very, very different for a defendant who's being asked to go on with the litigation because the likelihood of them getting fees is so much smaller. I think there was never any significant likelihood of anybody getting fees under a proper application of the Second Circuit's rule here, because obviously both sides had objectively reasonable positions. And I just don't think that that is something that would have happened in the past. You've got a willfulness found below. How do you get a willfulness found in a situation where you know there's a circuit where there's a chance of a split court, court of four? Well, the conduct was intentional, but the law was 50-50. There was a complete coin flip. And so it seems to me that while he says we don't want to predetermine discretion here, the reality is you have to have some structure to the decision making so people can predict what the outcome is going to be and be incentivized. Otherwise, you just have a black box. You say, well, each district judge takes six factors that we're not going to really tell you how to decide them. And then you're not doing what Fogarty asks. What Fogarty asks is use the fee decision, whether it's award fees, how much, to incentivize people to clarify the law because of the peculiar importance of copyright having a lot of money. Are you asking us in our decision to endorse the Second Circuit tests and reject the Ninth Circuit tests? Are articulated the way that the Ninth Circuit does? What exactly does the Second Circuit tests do? Ask us exactly what you want us to announce with respect to what the test should be or not be. We think the Second Circuit's test makes imminent sense in ought to be upheld. I would note, though, that since all of the factors here went the same way in the judgment of the district court, even if you decided that they shouldn't be giving substantial weight to one factor, there wouldn't be a basis for a reversal on this particular case. But we do think that starting with the objective reasonableness makes a lot of sense. It leads to the right outcome and the right incentives, and it gives people some basis for being able to figure out what's going to happen in the case and decide which cases to litigate to the end, in which cases to settle or simply to abandon. Kagan, why don't you answer the argument that you referred to patent cases, but the patent statutes these in exceptional cases. Right. The copyright act doesn't say that. I think that is, in fact, how it's played out that these are much more rare in patent cases than they are in copyright cases. It's certainly not true that they're exceptional in copyright cases, quite the opposite. It's clearly a large majority of cases are having fees awarded. The point, though, is even if you lay around that exceptionality requirement, the factors that you look at, was it badly litigated, should it not have been litigated, was there a reasonable basis, was there abuse of conduct, that's the fact that you should look at. That's what courts have always looked at. Why would you look at something else? I mean, that is the reason why one awards fees is either because somebody brought a case that shouldn't have or litigated a defense they shouldn't have or abused the process. And- You have a view, Mr. Smith, as to why it is that this reasonableness inquiry is producing such huge results as to plaintiffs and defendants, because it's a logical matter, you would think it shouldn't, that there wouldn't be this skew, unless you really think that defendants are taking so many more unreasonable litigating positions. And I guess that could be, but is there any other explanation or any, you know, thoughts you have about that? Part of it is the default judgments, where fees are routinely awarded because there's loady there to a post of them in very small amounts. But I think the other thing is, as the government points out in their brief, plaintiffs decide when to bring cases, defendants don't decide when to be defendants. And there are a lot of intentional infringers of copyrights out there in the world that we have now. And so people would be bizarre in a way if plaintiffs didn't have a higher percentage of claims they were reasonable, because they decide what case to bring, and they know that they're going to be spending money, and this is the investment in this case, and they decide to go ahead, whereas defendants are simply often just caught, you know, they were hoping to just slide out of the radar screen and put these infringing photographs upon their website or whatever it may be
. Otherwise, you just have a black box. You say, well, each district judge takes six factors that we're not going to really tell you how to decide them. And then you're not doing what Fogarty asks. What Fogarty asks is use the fee decision, whether it's award fees, how much, to incentivize people to clarify the law because of the peculiar importance of copyright having a lot of money. Are you asking us in our decision to endorse the Second Circuit tests and reject the Ninth Circuit tests? Are articulated the way that the Ninth Circuit does? What exactly does the Second Circuit tests do? Ask us exactly what you want us to announce with respect to what the test should be or not be. We think the Second Circuit's test makes imminent sense in ought to be upheld. I would note, though, that since all of the factors here went the same way in the judgment of the district court, even if you decided that they shouldn't be giving substantial weight to one factor, there wouldn't be a basis for a reversal on this particular case. But we do think that starting with the objective reasonableness makes a lot of sense. It leads to the right outcome and the right incentives, and it gives people some basis for being able to figure out what's going to happen in the case and decide which cases to litigate to the end, in which cases to settle or simply to abandon. Kagan, why don't you answer the argument that you referred to patent cases, but the patent statutes these in exceptional cases. Right. The copyright act doesn't say that. I think that is, in fact, how it's played out that these are much more rare in patent cases than they are in copyright cases. It's certainly not true that they're exceptional in copyright cases, quite the opposite. It's clearly a large majority of cases are having fees awarded. The point, though, is even if you lay around that exceptionality requirement, the factors that you look at, was it badly litigated, should it not have been litigated, was there a reasonable basis, was there abuse of conduct, that's the fact that you should look at. That's what courts have always looked at. Why would you look at something else? I mean, that is the reason why one awards fees is either because somebody brought a case that shouldn't have or litigated a defense they shouldn't have or abused the process. And- You have a view, Mr. Smith, as to why it is that this reasonableness inquiry is producing such huge results as to plaintiffs and defendants, because it's a logical matter, you would think it shouldn't, that there wouldn't be this skew, unless you really think that defendants are taking so many more unreasonable litigating positions. And I guess that could be, but is there any other explanation or any, you know, thoughts you have about that? Part of it is the default judgments, where fees are routinely awarded because there's loady there to a post of them in very small amounts. But I think the other thing is, as the government points out in their brief, plaintiffs decide when to bring cases, defendants don't decide when to be defendants. And there are a lot of intentional infringers of copyrights out there in the world that we have now. And so people would be bizarre in a way if plaintiffs didn't have a higher percentage of claims they were reasonable, because they decide what case to bring, and they know that they're going to be spending money, and this is the investment in this case, and they decide to go ahead, whereas defendants are simply often just caught, you know, they were hoping to just slide out of the radar screen and put these infringing photographs upon their website or whatever it may be. And so it doesn't strike me as surprising at all, actually, that we have this disparity that the standard is unfair, or is anything less than even handed. It simply means that the facts on the ground are leading to a difference in the outcome in percentages, which we have a lot of different percentages here, but a lot of defendants are getting fees too, even in the second circuit, according to their own statistics half the time. So it's not like it's entirely one sided. The Court has no more questions. Thank you, counsel. Mr. Goldemberg? Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the Court. I'd like to start by picking up on this point that's gotten a fair bit of discussion about what the statistics are in the second circuit under the Matthew Bender standard, which says that objective reason will be given substantial weight. Looking at hundreds and hundreds of cases in the second circuit in the district courts, I think that there's a lot of discretion that one can exercise in deciding whether to include cases in your count or not include cases in your count, whether you include default judgments, whether you include declaratory judgment situations, whether you include situations where the Court says, as a technical matter, you can't get fees because your motion was late, but in the alternative, by where to consider it, I would go on to the award or not award you fees anyway. So I think that there is some ground to quibble with some of the statistics, and I can tell you what statistics I came up with when I did this look, which are a little bit different, and I think show that there's not this vast disparity. And the statistics, this is in the district courts in the second circuit from Matthew Bender on, show that including default judgments in the count, 77 percent of the time when plaintiffs ask for fees, and it was decided on the merits in a reported decision, they got fees and of 53 percent of the time when defendants ask for fees. But if you drop out those default judgments, which as Mr. Smith indicated, are situations where the fee motion is effectively unopposed, where I think the defendant often looks very unreasonable by not having shown up to defend the case and where the fee amount is quite small by necessity because not much has happened in the case. Then the number of certs look much more similar, 59.7 percent for plaintiffs, 53 percent for defendants. So there's not this huge gulf between the percentages of time when plaintiffs and defendants are getting fees, at least by my count. And as I say, I recognize that there are different ways to do this count. So I think you have to take all these numbers with a little bit of a grain of salt. But I don't think any standard in the world would give you equal numbers of plaintiffs and defendants getting attorneys fees and Matthew Bender test is neutral. It is even handed on its face. It says very clearly that plaintiffs and defendants should be treated in the same way. And if the court thought that that somehow weren't being carried out properly in the second circuit, I think the court could emphasize that, and it wouldn't be a reason to reject the second circuit's test. With respect to giving objective reasonableness substantial weight, I would like to point out that that is the approach that this court took in the Martin decision, which was a case about removal and remand, and which involved Martin versus Franklin, which was a case that involved a statute that, much like the statute here, just gave broad discretion to district courts without a lot of standards to guide them
. And so it doesn't strike me as surprising at all, actually, that we have this disparity that the standard is unfair, or is anything less than even handed. It simply means that the facts on the ground are leading to a difference in the outcome in percentages, which we have a lot of different percentages here, but a lot of defendants are getting fees too, even in the second circuit, according to their own statistics half the time. So it's not like it's entirely one sided. The Court has no more questions. Thank you, counsel. Mr. Goldemberg? Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the Court. I'd like to start by picking up on this point that's gotten a fair bit of discussion about what the statistics are in the second circuit under the Matthew Bender standard, which says that objective reason will be given substantial weight. Looking at hundreds and hundreds of cases in the second circuit in the district courts, I think that there's a lot of discretion that one can exercise in deciding whether to include cases in your count or not include cases in your count, whether you include default judgments, whether you include declaratory judgment situations, whether you include situations where the Court says, as a technical matter, you can't get fees because your motion was late, but in the alternative, by where to consider it, I would go on to the award or not award you fees anyway. So I think that there is some ground to quibble with some of the statistics, and I can tell you what statistics I came up with when I did this look, which are a little bit different, and I think show that there's not this vast disparity. And the statistics, this is in the district courts in the second circuit from Matthew Bender on, show that including default judgments in the count, 77 percent of the time when plaintiffs ask for fees, and it was decided on the merits in a reported decision, they got fees and of 53 percent of the time when defendants ask for fees. But if you drop out those default judgments, which as Mr. Smith indicated, are situations where the fee motion is effectively unopposed, where I think the defendant often looks very unreasonable by not having shown up to defend the case and where the fee amount is quite small by necessity because not much has happened in the case. Then the number of certs look much more similar, 59.7 percent for plaintiffs, 53 percent for defendants. So there's not this huge gulf between the percentages of time when plaintiffs and defendants are getting fees, at least by my count. And as I say, I recognize that there are different ways to do this count. So I think you have to take all these numbers with a little bit of a grain of salt. But I don't think any standard in the world would give you equal numbers of plaintiffs and defendants getting attorneys fees and Matthew Bender test is neutral. It is even handed on its face. It says very clearly that plaintiffs and defendants should be treated in the same way. And if the court thought that that somehow weren't being carried out properly in the second circuit, I think the court could emphasize that, and it wouldn't be a reason to reject the second circuit's test. With respect to giving objective reasonableness substantial weight, I would like to point out that that is the approach that this court took in the Martin decision, which was a case about removal and remand, and which involved Martin versus Franklin, which was a case that involved a statute that, much like the statute here, just gave broad discretion to district courts without a lot of standards to guide them. And what the court said in that case is, the discretion isn't whim. In order for like cases to be treated alike, district courts discretion should be guided in certain ways so that there can be predictability and so that there can be, that principle of justice can be upheld. Well, you didn't have any absence of express statutory restrictions. You didn't have the sort of situation you have here where you're concerned about encouraging people to move for remand or discouraging people from filing for fees under remand. The policy sort of pushed all one way in Martin. Well, it's true that only one side in Martin could get fees. That's true. When the case is remanded, so the person's been unsuccessful in removing, that's when fees are awarded, but nevertheless, like any fee shifting session, it is taking into account incentives on both sides, whether you should try to remove the case, whether you should move to remand the case, if you're on the other side. And what happens in the copyright world because of this Court's forward decision is that those incentives are judged as to plaintiffs and defendants because both of them can get fees. But I don't think the underlying policies are different. In Martin, the Court wasn't looking at anything that was specific to that statute, to a history or to any policy that was specific to that statute at all, but what the Court said was, objective reasonableness is the touch zone. And yes, it may be true that in some cases where the losing party has been objectively reasonable, fees are appropriate in any event because this is an equitable matter, and we don't want to restrict the district's records discretion, and it's hard to imagine every single case that could possibly come up in the future. And that is equivalent to what the Second Circuit has done here. So it's very consistent with the approach that the Court has taken to other fee shifting statutes where there's broad discretion. It is also- It's suggested that he thought that the times in which the reasonableness inquiry would be outweighed is if you see real litigation misconduct. Is that your sense, too? Or is there anything else that actually is capable of outweighing it? My sense is that that is probably going to be the most frequent circumstance in which it would be outweighed, and there are, as Mr. Smith pointed out, some cases in the Second Circuit like that, leave a video, Zaluski cases where even though the losing party was objectively reasonable, the Court said there's been some misconduct here and so an award of fees may be appropriate or the district court should go back and see if there was misconduct here. Maybe. There are other other examples as well that I'd like to point out beyond that. And one example comes from the Six Circuit, and there are cases called WB Music and Bridgeport Music, and that was a situation where a plaintiff indiscriminately brought hundreds and hundreds and hundreds of claims, some of which were objectively reasonable and some of which were not objectively reasonable. And what the Court said there was, yes, it's true that your claim was objectively reasonable even though you didn't succeed, but you've proceeded in this unreasonable fashion. And so there's a strong deterrence factor that's playing in here. We don't want people to do this. We want to stop people from doing this in the future, and so we're going to award attorneys fees in that situation
. And what the court said in that case is, the discretion isn't whim. In order for like cases to be treated alike, district courts discretion should be guided in certain ways so that there can be predictability and so that there can be, that principle of justice can be upheld. Well, you didn't have any absence of express statutory restrictions. You didn't have the sort of situation you have here where you're concerned about encouraging people to move for remand or discouraging people from filing for fees under remand. The policy sort of pushed all one way in Martin. Well, it's true that only one side in Martin could get fees. That's true. When the case is remanded, so the person's been unsuccessful in removing, that's when fees are awarded, but nevertheless, like any fee shifting session, it is taking into account incentives on both sides, whether you should try to remove the case, whether you should move to remand the case, if you're on the other side. And what happens in the copyright world because of this Court's forward decision is that those incentives are judged as to plaintiffs and defendants because both of them can get fees. But I don't think the underlying policies are different. In Martin, the Court wasn't looking at anything that was specific to that statute, to a history or to any policy that was specific to that statute at all, but what the Court said was, objective reasonableness is the touch zone. And yes, it may be true that in some cases where the losing party has been objectively reasonable, fees are appropriate in any event because this is an equitable matter, and we don't want to restrict the district's records discretion, and it's hard to imagine every single case that could possibly come up in the future. And that is equivalent to what the Second Circuit has done here. So it's very consistent with the approach that the Court has taken to other fee shifting statutes where there's broad discretion. It is also- It's suggested that he thought that the times in which the reasonableness inquiry would be outweighed is if you see real litigation misconduct. Is that your sense, too? Or is there anything else that actually is capable of outweighing it? My sense is that that is probably going to be the most frequent circumstance in which it would be outweighed, and there are, as Mr. Smith pointed out, some cases in the Second Circuit like that, leave a video, Zaluski cases where even though the losing party was objectively reasonable, the Court said there's been some misconduct here and so an award of fees may be appropriate or the district court should go back and see if there was misconduct here. Maybe. There are other other examples as well that I'd like to point out beyond that. And one example comes from the Six Circuit, and there are cases called WB Music and Bridgeport Music, and that was a situation where a plaintiff indiscriminately brought hundreds and hundreds and hundreds of claims, some of which were objectively reasonable and some of which were not objectively reasonable. And what the Court said there was, yes, it's true that your claim was objectively reasonable even though you didn't succeed, but you've proceeded in this unreasonable fashion. And so there's a strong deterrence factor that's playing in here. We don't want people to do this. We want to stop people from doing this in the future, and so we're going to award attorneys fees in that situation. That is related, I think, to litigation misconduct, but it's not exactly the same thing, and it is a deterrence, it's focusing on the deterrence factor in the Fogarty Footnote. There's another example that's an example from the District Courts in the Second Circuit. It's a case called TIPS, exports, and it's an Eastern District of New York case, and that's a case where the defendant lost, and what the Court said again was, there's the deterrence factor that comes in here. The defendant was reasonable, objectively reasonable, and the petition on the facts and the law, but it appears that the defendant is going to take this just as a cost of doing business and keep on engaging in infringing conduct, because the award of fees isn't enough, I'm sorry, the award of damages is not enough to stop it. So in that situation, again, deterrence will override the fact that the losing party was a subjective reasonable. So I do think that the law is a part of the law. Is it pertinent in the government's view whether or not the party's seeking fees was represented by Pro Bono Council? I think it would be pertinent if you were to adopt an approach like petitioners approach where you took financial condition of the parties into account. If you're going to do that, then I think you would certainly need to look to see whether someone who appeared to be an impucunious party was actually represented Pro Bono was not responsible for their fees. But I take some issue with what petitioners counsel said that the financial condition of the parties is something that courts look to when they're deciding whether to make a fee award in the first instance. I'm not aware of any other circumstance where the courts look to the financial condition of the parties under a fee shifting statute to decide whether to award fees on a granular level. In other words, they look to the specific finances of the specific party before them. They certainly look at it when it comes time to decide what the amount of a fee award should be if they've already decided that they're going to award fees, and that I think is perfectly appropriate. And you'll see districts in the second circuit under the Matthew Bender standard doing exactly that if they have a very unreasonable, prosa plaintiff, for instance, they will say that a fee award may still be appropriate if that party loses, but perhaps the amount should be set lower. It will still be a deterrent to that person, but it won't be financially crushing to them. The look, Pogridi says it adds the need in particular circumstances to advance considerations of compensation and deterrence. Yes. It lists the reasonable fact, you know, reasonable position is one among four, says there could be others. Why? Why not stop right there? Maybe Marbury was a poor man. Maybe he didn't even want the job. Maybe he was just trying to try to create a situation where this country would have a structure of judicial review. I mean, can they take things like that? Why not? I mean, I don't know. It has to be consistent with the act. Why are we suddenly picking this one thing out of what could be a bunch of things? For a number of reasons. First of all, if you look at the factors that are mentioned in Pogridi, they actually many of them center around objective reasonfulness for volusness, deterrence, motivation, all of those are kind of circling around this concept of objective reasonfulness, which, as I pointed out, is pretty common to the courts' approach to other fee-shifting statutes, not only in Martin, but also as Mr
. That is related, I think, to litigation misconduct, but it's not exactly the same thing, and it is a deterrence, it's focusing on the deterrence factor in the Fogarty Footnote. There's another example that's an example from the District Courts in the Second Circuit. It's a case called TIPS, exports, and it's an Eastern District of New York case, and that's a case where the defendant lost, and what the Court said again was, there's the deterrence factor that comes in here. The defendant was reasonable, objectively reasonable, and the petition on the facts and the law, but it appears that the defendant is going to take this just as a cost of doing business and keep on engaging in infringing conduct, because the award of fees isn't enough, I'm sorry, the award of damages is not enough to stop it. So in that situation, again, deterrence will override the fact that the losing party was a subjective reasonable. So I do think that the law is a part of the law. Is it pertinent in the government's view whether or not the party's seeking fees was represented by Pro Bono Council? I think it would be pertinent if you were to adopt an approach like petitioners approach where you took financial condition of the parties into account. If you're going to do that, then I think you would certainly need to look to see whether someone who appeared to be an impucunious party was actually represented Pro Bono was not responsible for their fees. But I take some issue with what petitioners counsel said that the financial condition of the parties is something that courts look to when they're deciding whether to make a fee award in the first instance. I'm not aware of any other circumstance where the courts look to the financial condition of the parties under a fee shifting statute to decide whether to award fees on a granular level. In other words, they look to the specific finances of the specific party before them. They certainly look at it when it comes time to decide what the amount of a fee award should be if they've already decided that they're going to award fees, and that I think is perfectly appropriate. And you'll see districts in the second circuit under the Matthew Bender standard doing exactly that if they have a very unreasonable, prosa plaintiff, for instance, they will say that a fee award may still be appropriate if that party loses, but perhaps the amount should be set lower. It will still be a deterrent to that person, but it won't be financially crushing to them. The look, Pogridi says it adds the need in particular circumstances to advance considerations of compensation and deterrence. Yes. It lists the reasonable fact, you know, reasonable position is one among four, says there could be others. Why? Why not stop right there? Maybe Marbury was a poor man. Maybe he didn't even want the job. Maybe he was just trying to try to create a situation where this country would have a structure of judicial review. I mean, can they take things like that? Why not? I mean, I don't know. It has to be consistent with the act. Why are we suddenly picking this one thing out of what could be a bunch of things? For a number of reasons. First of all, if you look at the factors that are mentioned in Pogridi, they actually many of them center around objective reasonfulness for volusness, deterrence, motivation, all of those are kind of circling around this concept of objective reasonfulness, which, as I pointed out, is pretty common to the courts' approach to other fee-shifting statutes, not only in Martin, but also as Mr. Smith explained, in octane. So that's one example. There's another example, another reason though, that's very grounded in the copyright act itself. And that is the history of the copyright act and the ratification that Congress engaged in in 1976, when it chose to re-adopt essentially the same language from the 1909 copyright act, as to which courts have, through exercise with their discretion, over many years, worn a groove that said, generally, when losing party is reasonable, these are not going to be appropriate. That's equivalent to the Second Circuit's standard. Congress had every reason to know that that was the law under the existing language, because Congress was presented by experts, by the register of copyrights, whose job it is, to advise Congress on copyright policy, by the Brown study, which was an expert copyright office study that Congress had commissioned, all fees authorities said that. And so Congress had good reason to know that it was true. If you were thinking of this solely as a policy manner, if you didn't think that that evidence was all that overwhelming, why is it that this factor should be first among equals? For the, I think a lot of the reasons that Mr. Smith explained with respect to incentives. When you make that factor important, you're encouraging reasonable arguments, you're discouraging unreasonable arguments, you're increasing the chances that close cases where both sides are reasonable are going to actually get litigated to their conclusion, and therefore the law of copyright will be clarified, which is what this Court called for, in its Fogarty decision. If, on the other hand, you adopt something like the standard that Petitioner at least set forth in his brief, where you privilege the precedent-setting nature of the decision, then you have the tremendous unpredictability, tremendous uncertainty, and risk-averse parties are going to be deterred, and they won't litigate those close cases to the end, and the law will not be clarified. Thank you, counsel. Five minutes, Mr. Rosencrantz. Thank you, Your Honor. So, just a Skinzberg's question, which got picked up through the course of the argument, I think really gets to the nub of the matter. The magic language in Mr. Smith's presentation is that the second circuit has adopted the patent-ac standard. The patent-ac standard is different, and if octane means anything, it is we read the words that Congress actually wrote, exceptional circumstances, this Court defined, in exactly the way that the government and Wiley are defining this standard, we have to take Congress at its word that it meant something different. But it does mean something different in practice because as we were just told, it's unusual. There are not many fee-awards made in patent cases, much higher number in copyright cases. Yes, Your Honor. And that's because in every circuit but the second circuit, the district courts apply a different standard from the second circuit standard. That's why you have- We have the second circuit, and what was it? 50 percent of the defendants and some leaves, something percent, whatever
. Smith explained, in octane. So that's one example. There's another example, another reason though, that's very grounded in the copyright act itself. And that is the history of the copyright act and the ratification that Congress engaged in in 1976, when it chose to re-adopt essentially the same language from the 1909 copyright act, as to which courts have, through exercise with their discretion, over many years, worn a groove that said, generally, when losing party is reasonable, these are not going to be appropriate. That's equivalent to the Second Circuit's standard. Congress had every reason to know that that was the law under the existing language, because Congress was presented by experts, by the register of copyrights, whose job it is, to advise Congress on copyright policy, by the Brown study, which was an expert copyright office study that Congress had commissioned, all fees authorities said that. And so Congress had good reason to know that it was true. If you were thinking of this solely as a policy manner, if you didn't think that that evidence was all that overwhelming, why is it that this factor should be first among equals? For the, I think a lot of the reasons that Mr. Smith explained with respect to incentives. When you make that factor important, you're encouraging reasonable arguments, you're discouraging unreasonable arguments, you're increasing the chances that close cases where both sides are reasonable are going to actually get litigated to their conclusion, and therefore the law of copyright will be clarified, which is what this Court called for, in its Fogarty decision. If, on the other hand, you adopt something like the standard that Petitioner at least set forth in his brief, where you privilege the precedent-setting nature of the decision, then you have the tremendous unpredictability, tremendous uncertainty, and risk-averse parties are going to be deterred, and they won't litigate those close cases to the end, and the law will not be clarified. Thank you, counsel. Five minutes, Mr. Rosencrantz. Thank you, Your Honor. So, just a Skinzberg's question, which got picked up through the course of the argument, I think really gets to the nub of the matter. The magic language in Mr. Smith's presentation is that the second circuit has adopted the patent-ac standard. The patent-ac standard is different, and if octane means anything, it is we read the words that Congress actually wrote, exceptional circumstances, this Court defined, in exactly the way that the government and Wiley are defining this standard, we have to take Congress at its word that it meant something different. But it does mean something different in practice because as we were just told, it's unusual. There are not many fee-awards made in patent cases, much higher number in copyright cases. Yes, Your Honor. And that's because in every circuit but the second circuit, the district courts apply a different standard from the second circuit standard. That's why you have- We have the second circuit, and what was it? 50 percent of the defendants and some leaves, something percent, whatever. It's a much higher percentage than in patent cases. Agreed Your Honor, and it's important to understand why. Our numbers are 44 percent and 85 percent. One can quibble about the numbers, but I have to emphasize neither Mr. Smith nor the government has come forward with a single case in which a defendant got these where the plaintiff was not being reasonable. In every single one of their cases in the second circuit when a defendant got these, is because the plaintiff's position was unlegal, was unreasonable, or the plaintiff took unreasonable positions within the litigation. There is not a single case in the second circuit where anything other than unreasonable this carried the day. I want to say a word about history because there's been a lot of suggestion that the history before 1976 and the Copyright Act was an exceptional circumstances standard. It wasn't. There is not a single case that the government or-or-wily has cited, not one case that adopts the Matthew Bender standard across the board. So, sure, that is pre-1976 I'm talking about. So, sure, there were a lot of cases where unreasonable plaintiffs or defendants were hit with ease. There were cases where the reasonableness of a position for the district court carried the day, but not one case that ever said, here's how we should figure this out. All of the studies that the government has referred to are studies that admitted that there was actually no one standard. This Court has quoted the, I'm sorry, this Court in Fogarty, underscored that there was no standard that predated 1976, and even the cases that Wily cites, half of them are cases where one of the parties was unreasonable. That leaves only four cases, and those are all cases that are consistent with what we're saying the rule was. Final point, if we're talking about incentives, the difference between my position and Mr. Smith's position is that he wants a rule that decides upfront for all district courts that this is the way you will put on something, and I want a rule consistent with Congress's language and the use of the word may, that trusts district courts to figure out what the right incentives and disincentives are and to figure out what the value is to put unreasonable. And that's an awfully hard task for a district judge to perform what are, you know, what is, what will, further the purposes of the Copyright Act or what is most faithful to the Copyright Act. District court judges are going to see that very differently, and there won't be any consistency if that's what they're required to do or authorize to do. Your Honor, what will emerge is what's emerged in the Ninth Circuit, a common law of equity, where courts are following each other's decisions, and yes, there will be some variability, but the variability is invited by Congress in the word may. Unreasonable litigants will always be hit with attorney's fees, not because there's any particular weight put on it by a court of appeals, but because that's what district courts will do. But reasonable positions should be hit with attorney's fees or not, depending upon whether the court believes that the public was benefited by the litigation position. Thank you, Counsel
. Thank you, Your Honor. The case is submitted